Contents 1 Start 1.1 Economic indicators 2 Causes 2.1 Mainstream explanations 2.1.1 Keynesian 2.1.2 Monetarist 2.1.3 Common position 2.1.4 Additional modern nonmonetary explanations 2.1.4.1 Debt deflation 2.1.4.2 Expectations hypothesis 2.2 Heterodox theories 2.2.1 Austrian School 2.2.2 Marxist 2.2.3 Inequality 2.2.4 Productivity shock 3 Worsening of global depression 3.1 Gold standard 3.2 Breakdown of international trade 3.2.1 Effect of tariffs 3.3 German banking crisis of 1931 and British crisis 4 Turning point and recovery 4.1 Role of women and household economics 4.2 World War II and recovery 5 Effects 5.1 Australia 5.2 Canada 5.3 Chile 5.4 China 5.5 France 5.6 Germany 5.7 Greece 5.8 Iceland 5.9 Ireland 5.10 Italy 5.11 Japan 5.12 Latin America 5.13 Netherlands 5.14 New Zealand 5.15 Portugal 5.16 Puerto Rico 5.17 South Africa 5.18 Soviet Union 5.19 Spain 5.20 Sweden 5.21 Thailand 5.22 United Kingdom 5.23 United States 6 Literature 7 Naming 7.1 Other "great depressions" 8 Comparison with the Great Recession 9 See also 10 References 11 Further reading 11.1 Contemporary 12 External links


Start See also: Timeline of the Great Depression The Dow Jones Industrial, 1928–30 Economic historians usually attribute the start of the Great Depression to the sudden devastating collapse of U.S. stock market prices on October 29, 1929, known as Black Tuesday. However,[11] some dispute this conclusion and see the stock crash as a symptom, rather than a cause, of the Great Depression.[6][12] Even after the Wall Street Crash of 1929 optimism persisted for some time. John D. Rockefeller said "These are days when many are discouraged. In the 93 years of my life, depressions have come and gone. Prosperity has always returned and will again."[13] The stock market turned upward in early 1930, returning to early 1929 levels by April. This was still almost 30% below the peak of September 1929.[14] Together, government and business spent more in the first half of 1930 than in the corresponding period of the previous year. On the other hand, consumers, many of whom had suffered severe losses in the stock market the previous year, cut back their expenditures by 10%. In addition, beginning in the mid-1930s, a severe drought ravaged the agricultural heartland of the U.S.[15] Unemployed men outside a soup kitchen opened by Al Capone in Depression-era Chicago, Illinois, U.S., 1931 By mid-1930, interest rates had dropped to low levels, but expected deflation and the continuing reluctance of people to borrow meant that consumer spending and investment were depressed.[16] By May 1930, automobile sales had declined to below the levels of 1928. Prices in general began to decline, although wages held steady in 1930. Then a deflationary spiral started in 1931. Conditions were worse in farming areas, where commodity prices plunged and in mining and logging areas, where unemployment was high and there were few other jobs.[citation needed] The decline in the U.S. economy was the factor that pulled down most other countries at first; then, internal weaknesses or strengths in each country made conditions worse or better. Frantic attempts to shore up the economies of individual nations through protectionist policies, such as the 1930 U.S. Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act and retaliatory tariffs in other countries, exacerbated the collapse in global trade.[17] By late 1930, a steady decline in the world economy had set in, which did not reach bottom until 1933.[citation needed] Economic indicators Change in economic indicators 1929–32[18] United States Great Britain France Germany Industrial production −46% −23% −24% −41% Wholesale prices −32% −33% −34% −29% Foreign trade −70% −60% −54% −61% Unemployment +607% +129% +214% +232%


Causes Main article: Causes of the Great Depression Money supply decreased considerably between Black Tuesday and the Bank Holiday in March 1933 when there were massive bank runs across the United States. Crowd gathering at the intersection of Wall Street and Broad Street after the 1929 crash U.S. industrial production (1928–39) The two classical competing theories of the Great Depression are the Keynesian (demand-driven) and the monetarist explanation. There are also various heterodox theories that downplay or reject the explanations of the Keynesians and monetarists. The consensus among demand-driven theories is that a large-scale loss of confidence led to a sudden reduction in consumption and investment spending. Once panic and deflation set in, many people believed they could avoid further losses by keeping clear of the markets. Holding money became profitable as prices dropped lower and a given amount of money bought ever more goods, exacerbating the drop in demand. Monetarists believe that the Great Depression started as an ordinary recession, but the shrinking of the money supply greatly exacerbated the economic situation, causing a recession to descend into the Great Depression. Economists and economic historians are almost evenly split as to whether the traditional monetary explanation that monetary forces were the primary cause of the Great Depression is right, or the traditional Keynesian explanation that a fall in autonomous spending, particularly investment, is the primary explanation for the onset of the Great Depression.[19] Today the controversy is of lesser importance since there is mainstream support for the debt deflation theory and the expectations hypothesis that building on the monetary explanation of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz add non-monetary explanations. There is consensus that the Federal Reserve System should have cut short the process of monetary deflation and banking collapse. If they had done this, the economic downturn would have been far less severe and much shorter.[20] Mainstream explanations Keynesian British economist John Maynard Keynes argued in The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money that lower aggregate expenditures in the economy contributed to a massive decline in income and to employment that was well below the average. In such a situation, the economy reached equilibrium at low levels of economic activity and high unemployment. Keynes' basic idea was simple: to keep people fully employed, governments have to run deficits when the economy is slowing, as the private sector would not invest enough to keep production at the normal level and bring the economy out of recession. Keynesian economists called on governments during times of economic crisis to pick up the slack by increasing government spending and/or cutting taxes. As the Depression wore on, Franklin D. Roosevelt tried public works, farm subsidies, and other devices to restart the U.S. economy, but never completely gave up trying to balance the budget. According to the Keynesians, this improved the economy, but Roosevelt never spent enough to bring the economy out of recession until the start of World War II.[21] Monetarist The Great Depression in the U.S. from a monetary view. Real gross domestic product in 1996-Dollar (blue), price index (red), money supply M2 (green) and number of banks (grey). All data adjusted to 1929 = 100%. Crowd at New York's American Union Bank during a bank run early in the Great Depression Monetarists follow the explanation given by Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz. They argue that the Great Depression was caused by the banking crisis that caused one-third of all banks to vanish, a reduction of bank shareholder wealth and more importantly monetary contraction by 35%. This caused a price drop by 33% (deflation).[22] By not lowering interest rates, by not increasing the monetary base and by not injecting liquidity into the banking system to prevent it from crumbling the Federal Reserve passively watched the transforming of a normal recession into the Great Depression. Friedman argued that the downward turn in the economy, starting with the stock market crash, would merely have been an ordinary recession if the Federal Reserve had taken aggressive action.[23][24][25] The Federal Reserve allowed some large public bank failures – particularly that of the New York Bank of United States – which produced panic and widespread runs on local banks, and the Federal Reserve sat idly by while banks collapsed. He claimed that, if the Fed had provided emergency lending to these key banks, or simply bought government bonds on the open market to provide liquidity and increase the quantity of money after the key banks fell, all the rest of the banks would not have fallen after the large ones did, and the money supply would not have fallen as far and as fast as it did.[26] With significantly less money to go around, businessmen could not get new loans and could not even get their old loans renewed, forcing many to stop investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve for inaction, especially the New York Branch.[27] One reason why the Federal Reserve did not act to limit the decline of the money supply was the gold standard. At that time, the amount of credit the Federal Reserve could issue was limited by the Federal Reserve Act, which required 40% gold backing of Federal Reserve Notes issued. By the late 1920s, the Federal Reserve had almost hit the limit of allowable credit that could be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit was in the form of Federal Reserve demand notes.[28] A "promise of gold" is not as good as "gold in the hand", particularly when they only had enough gold to cover 40% of the Federal Reserve Notes outstanding. During the bank panics a portion of those demand notes were redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit its limit on allowable credit, any reduction in gold in its vaults had to be accompanied by a greater reduction in credit. On April 5, 1933, President Roosevelt signed Executive Order 6102 making the private ownership of gold certificates, coins and bullion illegal, reducing the pressure on Federal Reserve gold.[28] Common position From the point of view of today's mainstream schools of economic thought, government should strive to keep the interconnected macroeconomic aggregates money supply and/or aggregate demand on a stable growth path. When threatened by the forecast of a depression central banks should pour liquidity into the banking system and the government should cut taxes and accelerate spending in order to keep the nominal money stock and total nominal demand from collapsing.[29] At the beginning of the Great Depression most economists believed in Say's law and the self-equilibrating powers of the market and failed to explain the severity of the Depression. Outright leave-it-alone liquidationism was a position mainly held by the Austrian School.[30] The liquidationist position was that a depression is good medicine. The idea was the benefit of a depression was to liquidate failed investments and businesses that have been made obsolete by technological development in order to release factors of production (capital and labor) from unproductive uses so that these could be redeployed in other sectors of the technologically dynamic economy. They argued that even if self-adjustment of the economy took mass bankruptcies, then so be it.[30] An increasingly common view among economic historians is that the adherence of some Federal Reserve policymakers to the liquidationist thesis led to disastrous consequences.[31] Regarding the policies of President Hoover, economists like Barry Eichengreen and J. Bradford DeLong point out that President Hoover tried to keep the federal budget balanced until 1932, when he lost confidence in his Secretary of the Treasury Andrew Mellon and replaced him.[30][31][32] Despite liquidationist expectations, a large proportion of the capital stock was not redeployed but vanished during the first years of the Great Depression. According to a study by Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence Summers, the recession caused a drop of net capital accumulation to pre-1924 levels by 1933.[33] Milton Friedman called the leave-it-alone liquidationism "dangerous nonsense".[29] He wrote: “ I think the Austrian business-cycle theory has done the world a great deal of harm. If you go back to the 1930s, which is a key point, here you had the Austrians sitting in London, Hayek and Lionel Robbins, and saying you just have to let the bottom drop out of the world. You've just got to let it cure itself. You can't do anything about it. You will only make it worse. … I think by encouraging that kind of do-nothing policy both in Britain and in the United States, they did harm.[31] ” Additional modern nonmonetary explanations The monetary explanation has two weaknesses. First it is not able to explain why the demand for money was falling more rapidly than the supply during the initial downturn in 1930–31.[19] Second it is not able to explain why in March 1933 a recovery took place although short term interest rates remained close to zero and the Money supply was still falling. These questions are addressed by modern explanations that build on the monetary explanation of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz but add non-monetary explanations. Debt deflation Crowds outside the Bank of United States in New York after its failure in 1931 Irving Fisher argued that the predominant factor leading to the Great Depression was a vicious circle of deflation and growing over-indebtedness.[34] He outlined nine factors interacting with one another under conditions of debt and deflation to create the mechanics of boom to bust. The chain of events proceeded as follows: Debt liquidation and distress selling Contraction of the money supply as bank loans are paid off A fall in the level of asset prices A still greater fall in the net worth of businesses, precipitating bankruptcies A fall in profits A reduction in output, in trade and in employment Pessimism and loss of confidence Hoarding of money A fall in nominal interest rates and a rise in deflation adjusted interest rates[34] During the Crash of 1929 preceding the Great Depression, margin requirements were only 10%.[35] Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers called in these loans, which could not be paid back.[36] Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple bank runs. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.[36] Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929, and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 U.S. banks failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s). By April 1933, around $7 billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those left unlicensed after the March Bank Holiday.[37] Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans which the borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, capital investment and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending.[36] Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A vicious cycle developed and the downward spiral accelerated. The liquidation of debt could not keep up with the fall of prices which it caused. The mass effect of the stampede to liquidate increased the value of each dollar owed, relative to the value of declining asset holdings. The very effort of individuals to lessen their burden of debt effectively increased it. Paradoxically, the more the debtors paid, the more they owed.[34] This self-aggravating process turned a 1930 recession into a 1933 great depression. Fisher's debt-deflation theory initially lacked mainstream influence because of the counter-argument that debt-deflation represented no more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to another (creditors). Pure re-distributions should have no significant macroeconomic effects. Building on both the monetary hypothesis of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz as well as the debt deflation hypothesis of Irving Fisher, Ben Bernanke developed an alternative way in which the financial crisis affected output. He builds on Fisher's argument that dramatic declines in the price level and nominal incomes lead to increasing real debt burdens which in turn leads to debtor insolvency and consequently leads to lowered aggregate demand, a further decline in the price level then results in a debt deflationary spiral. According to Bernanke, a small decline in the price level simply reallocates wealth from debtors to creditors without doing damage to the economy. But when the deflation is severe falling asset prices along with debtor bankruptcies lead to a decline in the nominal value of assets on bank balance sheets. Banks will react by tightening their credit conditions, that in turn leads to a credit crunch which does serious harm to the economy. A credit crunch lowers investment and consumption and results in declining aggregate demand which additionally contributes to the deflationary spiral.[38][39][40] Expectations hypothesis Since economic mainstream turned to the new neoclassical synthesis, expectations are a central element of macroeconomic models. According to Peter Temin, Barry Wigmore, Gauti B. Eggertsson and Christina Romer, the key to recovery and to ending the Great Depression was brought about by a successful management of public expectations. The thesis is based on the observation that after years of deflation and a very severe recession important economic indicators turned positive in March 1933 when Franklin D. Roosevelt took office. Consumer prices turned from deflation to a mild inflation, industrial production bottomed out in March 1933, and investment doubled in 1933 with a turnaround in March 1933. There were no monetary forces to explain that turn around. Money supply was still falling and short term interest rates remained close to zero. Before March 1933 people expected further deflation and a recession so that even interest rates at zero did not stimulate investment. But when Roosevelt announced major regime changes people began to expect inflation and an economic expansion. With these positive expectations, interest rates at zero began to stimulate investment just as they were expected to do. Roosevelt's fiscal and monetary policy regime change helped to make his policy objectives credible. The expectation of higher future income and higher future inflation stimulated demand and investments. The analysis suggests that the elimination of the policy dogmas of the gold standard, a balanced budget in times of crises and small government led endogenously to a large shift in expectation that accounts for about 70–80 percent of the recovery of output and prices from 1933 to 1937. If the regime change had not happened and the Hoover policy had continued, the economy would have continued its free fall in 1933, and output would have been 30% lower in 1937 than in 1933.[41][42][43] The recession of 1937–38, which slowed down economic recovery from the Great Depression, is explained by fears of the population that the moderate tightening of the monetary and fiscal policy in 1937 would be first steps to a restoration of the pre-March 1933 policy regime.[44] Heterodox theories Austrian School Theorists of the "Austrian School" who wrote about the Depression include Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek and American economist Murray Rothbard, who wrote America's Great Depression (1963). In their view and like the monetarists, the Federal Reserve, which was created in 1913, shoulders much of the blame; but in opposition to the monetarists, they argue that the key cause of the Depression was the expansion of the money supply in the 1920s that led to an unsustainable credit-driven boom.[45] In the Austrian view it was this inflation of the money supply that led to an unsustainable boom in both asset prices (stocks and bonds) and capital goods. By the time the Fed belatedly tightened in 1928, it was far too late and, in the Austrian view, a significant economic contraction was inevitable.[45] In February 1929 Hayek published a paper predicting the Federal Reserve's actions would lead to a crisis starting in the stock and credit markets.[46] According to Rothbard, government support for failed enterprises and keeping wages above their market values actually prolonged the Depression.[47] Hayek, unlike Rothbard, believed since the 1970s, along with the monetarists, that the Federal Reserve further contributed to the problems of the Depression by permitting the money supply to shrink during the earliest years of the Depression.[48] However, in 1932 and 1934 Hayek had criticised the FED and the Bank of England for not taking a more contractionary stance.[49] Hans Sennholz argued that most boom and busts that plagued the American economy in 1819–20, 1839–43, 1857–60, 1873–78, 1893–97, and 1920–21, were generated by government creating a boom through easy money and credit, which was soon followed by the inevitable bust. The spectacular crash of 1929 followed five years of reckless credit expansion by the Federal Reserve System under the Coolidge Administration. The passing of the Sixteenth Amendment, the passage of The Federal Reserve Act, rising government deficits, the passage of the Hawley-Smoot Tariff Act, and the Revenue Act of 1932, exacerbated the crisis, prolonging it.[50] Ludwig von Mises wrote in the 1930s: "Credit expansion cannot increase the supply of real goods. It merely brings about a rearrangement. It diverts capital investment away from the course prescribed by the state of economic wealth and market conditions. It causes production to pursue paths which it would not follow unless the economy were to acquire an increase in material goods. As a result, the upswing lacks a solid base. It is not a real prosperity. It is illusory prosperity. It did not develop from an increase in economic wealth, i.e. the accumulation of savings made available for productive investment. Rather, it arose because the credit expansion created the illusion of such an increase. Sooner or later, it must become apparent that this economic situation is built on sand."[51][52] Marxist Karl Marx saw recession and depression as unavoidable under free-market capitalism as there are no restrictions on accumulations of capital other than the market itself. In the Marxist view, capitalism tends to create unbalanced accumulations of wealth, leading to over-accumulations of capital which inevitably lead to a crisis. This especially sharp bust is a regular feature of the boom and bust pattern of what Marxists term "chaotic" capitalist development. It is a tenet of many Marxist groupings that such crises are inevitable and will be increasingly severe until the contradictions inherent in the mismatch between the mode of production and the development of productive forces reach the final point of failure. At which point, the crisis period encourages intensified class conflict and forces societal change.[53] Inequality Power farming displaces tenants from the land in the western dry cotton area. Childress County, Texas, 1938 Two economists of the 1920s, Waddill Catchings and William Trufant Foster, popularized a theory that influenced many policy makers, including Herbert Hoover, Henry A. Wallace, Paul Douglas, and Marriner Eccles. It held the economy produced more than it consumed, because the consumers did not have enough income. Thus the unequal distribution of wealth throughout the 1920s caused the Great Depression.[54][55] According to this view, the root cause of the Great Depression was a global over-investment in heavy industry capacity compared to wages and earnings from independent businesses, such as farms. The proposed solution was for the government to pump money into the consumers' pockets. That is, it must redistribute purchasing power, maintaining the industrial base, and re-inflating prices and wages to force as much of the inflationary increase in purchasing power into consumer spending. The economy was overbuilt, and new factories were not needed. Foster and Catchings recommended[56] federal and state governments to start large construction projects, a program followed by Hoover and Roosevelt. Productivity shock It cannot be emphasized too strongly that the [productivity, output and employment] trends we are describing are long-time trends and were thoroughly evident prior to 1929. These trends are in nowise the result of the present depression, nor are they the result of the World War. On the contrary, the present depression is a collapse resulting from these long-term trends. [57] — M. King Hubbert The first three decades of the 20th century saw economic output surge with electrification, mass production and motorized farm machinery, and because of the rapid growth in productivity there was a lot of excess production capacity and the work week was being reduced.[citation needed] The dramatic rise in productivity of major industries in the U.S. and the effects of productivity on output, wages and the work week are discussed by Spurgeon Bell in his book Productivity, Wages, and National Income (1940).[58]


Worsening of global depression This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (May 2016) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) The gold standard was the primary transmission mechanism of the Great Depression. Even countries that did not face bank failures and a monetary contraction first hand were forced to join the deflationary policy since higher interest rates in countries that performed a deflationary policy led to a gold outflow in countries with lower interest rates. Under the gold standard's price–specie flow mechanism, countries that lost gold but nevertheless wanted to maintain the gold standard had to permit their money supply to decrease and the domestic price level to decline (deflation).[59][60] There is also consensus that protectionist policies such as the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act helped to worsen the depression.[61] Gold standard The Depression in international perspective[62] Some economic studies have indicated that just as the downturn was spread worldwide by the rigidities of the Gold Standard, it was suspending gold convertibility (or devaluing the currency in gold terms) that did the most to make recovery possible.[63] Every major currency left the gold standard during the Great Depression. Great Britain was the first to do so. Facing speculative attacks on the pound and depleting gold reserves, in September 1931 the Bank of England ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on foreign exchange markets. Great Britain, Japan, and the Scandinavian countries left the gold standard in 1931. Other countries, such as Italy and the U.S., remained on the gold standard into 1932 or 1933, while a few countries in the so-called "gold bloc", led by France and including Poland, Belgium and Switzerland, stayed on the standard until 1935–36. According to later analysis, the earliness with which a country left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery. For example, Great Britain and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931, recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold much longer. Countries such as China, which had a silver standard, almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of its depression and the length of time of its recovery has been shown to be consistent for dozens of countries, including developing countries. This partly explains why the experience and length of the depression differed between national economies.[64] Breakdown of international trade Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in international trade after 1930 helped to worsen the depression, especially for countries significantly dependent on foreign trade. In a 1995 survey of American economic historians, two-thirds agreed that the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act at least worsened the Great Depression.[65] Most historians and economists partly blame the American Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act (enacted June 17, 1930) for worsening the depression by seriously reducing international trade and causing retaliatory tariffs in other countries. While foreign trade was a small part of overall economic activity in the U.S. and was concentrated in a few businesses like farming, it was a much larger factor in many other countries.[66] The average ad valorem rate of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–25 was 25.9% but under the new tariff it jumped to 50% during 1931–35. In dollar terms, American exports declined over the next four (4) years from about $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.7 billion in 1933; so, not only did the physical volume of exports fall, but also the prices fell by about 1/3 as written. Hardest hit were farm commodities such as wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber. Governments around the world took various steps into spending less money on foreign goods such as: "imposing tariffs, import quotas, and exchange controls". These restrictions formed a lot of tension between trade nations, causing a major deduction during the depression. Not all countries enforced the same measures of protectionism. Some countries raised tariffs drastically and enforced severe restrictions on foreign exchange transactions, while other countries condensed "trade and exchange restrictions only marginally":[67] "Countries that remained on the gold standard, keeping currencies fixed, were more likely to restrict foreign trade." These countries "resorted to protectionist policies to strengthen the balance of payments and limit gold losses." They hoped that these restrictions and depletions would hold the economic decline.[67] Countries that abandoned the gold standard, allowed their currencies to depreciate which caused their balance of payments to strengthen. It also freed up monetary policy so that central banks could lower interest rates and act as lenders of last resort. They possessed the best policy instruments to fight the Depression and did not need protectionism.[67] "The length and depth of a country’s economic downturn and the timing and vigor of its recovery is related to how long it remained on the gold standard. Countries abandoning the gold standard relatively early experienced relatively mild recessions and early recoveries. In contrast, countries remaining on the gold standard experienced prolonged slumps."[67] Effect of tariffs See also: Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act The consensus view among economists and economic historians is that the passage of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff exacerbated the Great Depression,[68] although there is disagreement as to how much. In the popular view, the Smoot-Hawley Tariff was a leading cause of the depression.[69][70] However, many economists hold the opinion that the tariff act did not greatly worsen the depression. German banking crisis of 1931 and British crisis It has been suggested that this section be split out into another article titled European banking crisis of 1931. (Discuss) (September 2017) The financial crisis escalated out of control in mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May.[71][72] This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political turmoil. With the rise in violence of Nazi and communist movements, as well as investor nervousness at harsh government financial policies.[73] Investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany, as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150 million marks in the first week of June, 540 million in the second, and 150 million in two days, June 19–20. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called for a moratorium on Payment of war reparations. This angered Paris, which depended on a steady flow of German payments, but it slowed the crisis down and the moratorium, was agreed to in July 1931. International conference in London later in July produced no agreements but on August 19 a standstill agreement froze Germany's foreign liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding from private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the process; it's nothing. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in July and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business failures more frequent in July, and spread to Romania and Hungary. The crisis continued to get worse in Germany, bringing political upheaval that finally led to the coming to power of Hitler's Nazi regime in January 1933.[74] The world financial crisis now began to overwhelm Britain; investors across the world started withdrawing their gold from London at the rate of £2½ millions a day.[75] Credits of £25 millions each from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15 millions fiduciary note slowed, but did not reverse the British crisis. The financial crisis now caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed; it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending and most controversially, to cut unemployment benefits 20%. The attack on welfare was totally unacceptable to the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but King George V insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "National government." The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off the gold standard, and suffered relatively less than other major countries in the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election the Labour Party was virtually destroyed, leaving MacDonald as Prime Minister for a largely Conservative coalition.[76][77]


Turning point and recovery The overall course of the Depression in the United States, as reflected in per-capita GDP (average income per person) shown in constant year 2000 dollars, plus some of the key events of the period. Dotted red line = long term trend 1920–1970.[78] In most countries of the world, recovery from the Great Depression began in 1933.[11] In the U.S., recovery began in early 1933,[11] but the U.S. did not return to 1929 GNP for over a decade and still had an unemployment rate of about 15% in 1940, albeit down from the high of 25% in 1933. The measurement of the unemployment rate in this time period was unsophisticated and complicated by the presence of massive underemployment, in which employers and workers engaged in rationing of jobs.[citation needed] There is no consensus among economists regarding the motive force for the U.S. economic expansion that continued through most of the Roosevelt years (and the 1937 recession that interrupted it). The common view among most economists is that Roosevelt's New Deal policies either caused or accelerated the recovery, although his policies were never aggressive enough to bring the economy completely out of recession. Some economists have also called attention to the positive effects from expectations of reflation and rising nominal interest rates that Roosevelt's words and actions portended.[79][80] It was the rollback of those same reflationary policies that led to the interrupting recession of 1937.[81][82] One contributing policy that reversed reflation was the Banking Act of 1935, which effectively raised reserve requirements, causing a monetary contraction that helped to thwart the recovery.[83] GDP returned to its upward trend in 1938.[citation needed] According to Christina Romer, the money supply growth caused by huge international gold inflows was a crucial source of the recovery of the United States economy, and that the economy showed little sign of self-correction. The gold inflows were partly due to devaluation of the U.S. dollar and partly due to deterioration of the political situation in Europe.[84] In their book, A Monetary History of the United States, Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz also attributed the recovery to monetary factors, and contended that it was much slowed by poor management of money by the Federal Reserve System. Former Chairman of the Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke agreed that monetary factors played important roles both in the worldwide economic decline and eventual recovery.[85] Bernanke also saw a strong role for institutional factors, particularly the rebuilding and restructuring of the financial system,[86] and pointed out that the Depression should be examined in an international perspective.[87] Role of women and household economics Women's primary role were as housewives; without a steady flow of family income, their work became much harder in dealing with food and clothing and medical care. Birthrates fell everywhere, as children were postponed until families could financially support them. The average birthrate for 14 major countries fell 12% from 19.3 births per thousand population in 1930, to 17.0 in 1935.[88] In Canada, half of Roman Catholic women defied Church teachings and used contraception to postpone births.[89] Among the few women in the labor force, layoffs were less common in the white-collar jobs and they were typically found in light manufacturing work. However, there was a widespread demand to limit families to one paid job, so that wives might lose employment if their husband was employed.[90][91][92] Across Britain, there was a tendency for married women to join the labor force, competing for part-time jobs especially.[93] In rural and small-town areas, women expanded their operation of vegetable gardens to include as much food production as possible. In the United States, agricultural organizations sponsored programs to teach housewives how to optimize their gardens and to raise poultry for meat and eggs.[94] In American cities, African American women quiltmakers enlarged their activities, promoted collaboration, and trained neophytes. Quilts were created for practical use from various inexpensive materials and increased social interaction for women and promoted camaraderie and personal fulfillment.[95] Oral history provides evidence for how housewives in a modern industrial city handled shortages of money and resources. Often they updated strategies their mothers used when they were growing up in poor families. Cheap foods were used, such as soups, beans and noodles. They purchased the cheapest cuts of meat—sometimes even horse meat—and recycled the Sunday roast into sandwiches and soups. They sewed and patched clothing, traded with their neighbors for outgrown items, and made do with colder homes. New furniture and appliances were postponed until better days. Many women also worked outside the home, or took boarders, did laundry for trade or cash, and did sewing for neighbors in exchange for something they could offer. Extended families used mutual aid—extra food, spare rooms, repair-work, cash loans—to help cousins and in-laws.[96] In Japan, official government policy was deflationary and the opposite of Keynesian spending. Consequently, the government launched a nationwide campaign to induce households to reduce their consumption, focusing attention on spending by housewives.[97] In Germany, the government tried to reshape private household consumption under the Four-Year Plan of 1936 to achieve German economic self-sufficiency. The Nazi women's organizations, other propaganda agencies and the authorities all attempted to shape such consumption as economic self-sufficiency was needed to prepare for and to sustain the coming war. The organizations, propaganda agencies and authorities employed slogans that called up traditional values of thrift and healthy living. However, these efforts were only partly successful in changing the behavior of housewives.[98] World War II and recovery A female factory worker in 1942, Fort Worth, Texas. Women entered the workforce as men were drafted into the armed forces The common view among economic historians is that the Great Depression ended with the advent of World War II. Many economists believe that government spending on the war caused or at least accelerated recovery from the Great Depression, though some consider that it did not play a very large role in the recovery. It did help in reducing unemployment.[11][99][100][101] The rearmament policies leading up to World War II helped stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937–39. By 1937, unemployment in Britain had fallen to 1.5 million. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak of war in 1939 ended unemployment.[102] When the United States entered into the war in 1941, it finally eliminated the last effects from the Great Depression and brought the U.S. unemployment rate down below 10%.[103] In the U.S., massive war spending doubled economic growth rates, either masking the effects of the Depression or essentially ending the Depression. Businessmen ignored the mounting national debt and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for greater output to take advantage of generous government contracts.[citation needed]


Effects This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (May 2016) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) An impoverished American family living in a shanty, 1936 The majority of countries set up relief programs and most underwent some sort of political upheaval, pushing them to the right. Many of the countries in Europe and Latin America that were democracies saw them overthrown by some form of dictatorship or authoritarian rule, most famously in Germany in 1933. The Dominion of Newfoundland gave up democracy voluntarily. Australia Main article: Great Depression in Australia Australia's dependence on agricultural and industrial exports meant it was one of the hardest-hit developed countries.[104] Falling export demand and commodity prices placed massive downward pressures on wages. Unemployment reached a record high of 29% in 1932,[105] with incidents of civil unrest becoming common. After 1932, an increase in wool and meat prices led to a gradual recovery.[106] Canada Main article: Great Depression in Canada Unemployed men march in Toronto, Ontario, Canada Harshly affected by both the global economic downturn and the Dust Bowl, Canadian industrial production had fallen to only 58% of the 1929 level by 1932, the second lowest level in the world after the United States, and well behind nations such as Britain, which fell to only 83% of the 1929 level. Total national income fell to 56% of the 1929 level, again worse than any nation apart from the United States. Unemployment reached 27% at the depth of the Depression in 1933.[107] Chile Main article: Great Depression in Chile The League of Nations labeled Chile the country hardest hit by the Great Depression because 80% of government revenue came from exports of copper and nitrates, which were in low demand. Chile initially felt the impact of the Great Depression in 1930, when GDP dropped 14%, mining income declined 27%, and export earnings fell 28%. By 1932, GDP had shrunk to less than half of what it had been in 1929, exacting a terrible toll in unemployment and business failures. Influenced profoundly by the Great Depression, many national leaders promoted the development of local industry in an effort to insulate the economy from future external shocks. After six years of government austerity measures, which succeeded in reestablishing Chile's creditworthiness, Chileans elected to office during the 1938–58 period a succession of center and left-of-center governments interested in promoting economic growth by means of government intervention. Prompted in part by the devastating 1939 Chillán earthquake, the Popular Front government of Pedro Aguirre Cerda created the Production Development Corporation (Corporación de Fomento de la Producción, CORFO) to encourage with subsidies and direct investments an ambitious program of import substitution industrialization. Consequently, as in other Latin American countries, protectionism became an entrenched aspect of the Chilean economy. China Main article: Nanjing Decade China was largely unaffected by the Depression, mainly by having stuck to the Silver standard. However, the U.S. silver purchase act of 1934 created an intolerable demand on China's silver coins, and so in the end the silver standard was officially abandoned in 1935 in favor of the four Chinese national banks' "legal note" issues. China and the British colony of Hong Kong, which followed suit in this regard in September 1935, would be the last to abandon the silver standard. In addition, the Nationalist Government also acted energetically to modernize the legal and penal systems, stabilize prices, amortize debts, reform the banking and currency systems, build railroads and highways, improve public health facilities, legislate against traffic in narcotics and augment industrial and agricultural production. On November 3, 1935, the government instituted the fiat currency (fapi) reform, immediately stabilizing prices and also raising revenues for the government. France Main article: Great Depression in France The crisis affected France a bit later than other countries, hitting around 1931.[108] While the 1920s grew at the very strong rate of 4.43% per year, the 1930s rate fell to only 0.63%.[109] The depression was relatively mild: unemployment peaked under 5%, the fall in production was at most 20% below the 1929 output; there was no banking crisis.[110] However, the depression had drastic effects on the local economy, and partly explains the February 6, 1934 riots and even more the formation of the Popular Front, led by SFIO socialist leader Léon Blum, which won the elections in 1936. Ultra-nationalist groups also saw increased popularity, although democracy prevailed into World War II. France's relatively high degree of self-sufficiency meant the damage was considerably less than in nations like Germany. Germany Main article: Weimar Republic Adolf Hitler speaking in 1935 The Great Depression hit Germany hard. The impact of the Wall Street Crash forced American banks to end the new loans that had been funding the repayments under the Dawes Plan and the Young Plan. The financial crisis escalated out of control and mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May.[72] This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political turmoil. With the rise in violence of Nazi and communist movements, as well as investor nervousness at harsh government financial policies.[73] Investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany, as confidence spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150 million marks in the first week of June, 540 million in the second, and 150 million in two days, June 19–20. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called for a moratorium on Payment of war reparations. This angered Paris, which depended on a steady flow of German payments, but it slowed the crisis down and the moratorium, was agreed to in July 1931. International conference in London later in July produced no agreements but on August 19 a standstill agreement froze Germany's foreign liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding from private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the process; it's nothing. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in July and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business failures more frequent in July, and spread to Romania and Hungary.[74] In 1932, 90% of German reparation payments were cancelled. (In the 1950s, Germany repaid all its missed reparations debts.) Widespread unemployment reached 25% as every sector was hurt. The government did not increase government spending to deal with Germany's growing crisis, as they were afraid that a high-spending policy could lead to a return of the hyperinflation that had affected Germany in 1923. Germany's Weimar Republic was hit hard by the depression, as American loans to help rebuild the German economy now stopped.[111] The unemployment rate reached nearly 30% in 1932, bolstering support for the Nazi (NSDAP) and Communist (KPD) parties, causing the collapse of the politically centrist Social Democratic Party. Hitler ran for the Presidency in 1932, and while he lost to the incumbent Hindenburg in the election, it marked a point during which both Nazi Party and the Communist parties rose in the years following the crash to altogether possess a Reichstag majority following the general election in July 1932.[112][113] Hitler followed an autarky economic policy, creating a network of client states and economic allies in central Europe and Latin America. By cutting wages and taking control of labor unions, plus public works spending, unemployment fell significantly by 1935. Large scale military spending played a major role in the recovery.[114] Greece Main article: Economic history of Greece and the Greek world The reverberations of the Great Depression hit Greece in 1932. The Bank of Greece tried to adopt deflationary policies to stave off the crises that were going on in other countries, but these largely failed. For a brief period the drachma was pegged to the U.S. dollar, but this was unsustainable given the country's large trade deficit and the only long-term effects of this were Greece's foreign exchange reserves being almost totally wiped out in 1932. Remittances from abroad declined sharply and the value of the drachma began to plummet from 77 drachmas to the dollar in March 1931 to 111 drachmas to the dollar in April, 1931. This was especially harmful to Greece as the country relied on imports from the UK, France and the Middle East for many necessities. Greece went off the gold standard in April, 1932 and declared a moratorium on all interest payments. The country also adopted protectionist policies such as import quotas, which a number of European countries did during the time period. Protectionist policies coupled with a weak drachma, stifling imports, allowed Greek industry to expand during the Great Depression. In 1939 Greek Industrial output was 179% that of 1928. These industries were for the most part "built on sand" as one report of the Bank of Greece put it, as without massive protection they would not have been able to survive. Despite the global depression, Greece managed to suffer comparatively little, averaging an average growth rate of 3.5% from 1932 to 1939. The dictatorial regime of Ioannis Metaxas took over the Greek government in 1936, and economic growth was strong in the years leading up to the Second World War. Iceland Icelandic post-World War I prosperity came to an end with the outbreak of the Great Depression. The Depression hit Iceland hard as the value of exports plummeted. The total value of Icelandic exports fell from 74 million kronur in 1929 to 48 million in 1932, and was not to rise again to the pre-1930 level until after 1939.[115] Government interference in the economy increased: "Imports were regulated, trade with foreign currency was monopolized by state-owned banks, and loan capital was largely distributed by state-regulated funds".[115] Due to the outbreak of the Spanish Civil War, which cut Iceland's exports of saltfish by half, the Depression lasted in Iceland until the outbreak of World War II (when prices for fish exports soared).[115] Ireland Main article: Economic history of the Republic of Ireland Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly have argued that : Ireland was a largely agrarian economy, trading almost exclusively with the UK, at the time of the Great Depression. Beef and dairy products comprised the bulk of exports, and Ireland fared well relative to many other commodity producers, particularly in the early years of the depression.[116][117][118][119] Italy Main article: Economic history of Italy The Great Depression hit Italy very hard.[120] As industries came close to failure they were bought out by the banks in a largely illusionary bail-out—the assets used to fund the purchases were largely worthless. This led to a financial crisis peaking in 1932 and major government intervention. The Industrial Reconstruction Institute (IRI) was formed in January 1933 and took control of the bank-owned companies, suddenly giving Italy the largest state-owned industrial sector in Europe (excluding the USSR). IRI did rather well with its new responsibilities—restructuring, modernising and rationalising as much as it could. It was a significant factor in post-1945 development. But it took the Italian economy until 1935 to recover the manufacturing levels of 1930—a position that was only 60% better than that of 1913.[121][122] Japan The Great Depression did not strongly affect Japan. The Japanese economy shrank by 8% during 1929–31. Japan's Finance Minister Takahashi Korekiyo was the first to implement what have come to be identified as Keynesian economic policies: first, by large fiscal stimulus involving deficit spending; and second, by devaluing the currency. Takahashi used the Bank of Japan to sterilize the deficit spending and minimize resulting inflationary pressures. Econometric studies have identified the fiscal stimulus as especially effective.[123] The devaluation of the currency had an immediate effect. Japanese textiles began to displace British textiles in export markets. The deficit spending proved to be most profound and went into the purchase of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the depression. By 1934, Takahashi realized that the economy was in danger of overheating, and to avoid inflation, moved to reduce the deficit spending that went towards armaments and munitions. This resulted in a strong and swift negative reaction from nationalists, especially those in the army, culminating in his assassination in the course of the February 26 Incident. This had a chilling effect on all civilian bureaucrats in the Japanese government. From 1934, the military's dominance of the government continued to grow. Instead of reducing deficit spending, the government introduced price controls and rationing schemes that reduced, but did not eliminate inflation, which remained a problem until the end of World War II. The deficit spending had a transformative effect on Japan. Japan's industrial production doubled during the 1930s. Further, in 1929 the list of the largest firms in Japan was dominated by light industries, especially textile companies (many of Japan's automakers, such as Toyota, have their roots in the textile industry). By 1940 light industry had been displaced by heavy industry as the largest firms inside the Japanese economy.[124] Latin America Main article: Great Depression in Latin America Because of high levels of U.S. investment in Latin American economies, they were severely damaged by the Depression. Within the region, Chile, Bolivia and Peru were particularly badly affected.[125] Before the 1929 crisis, links between the world economy and Latin American economies had been established through American and British investment in Latin American exports to the world. As a result, Latin Americans export industries felt the depression quickly. World prices for commodities such as wheat, coffee and copper plunged. Exports from all of Latin America to the U.S. fell in value from $1.2 billion in 1929 to $335 million in 1933, rising to $660 million in 1940. But on the other hand, the depression led the area governments to develop new local industries and expand consumption and production. Following the example of the New Deal, governments in the area approved regulations and created or improved welfare institutions that helped millions of new industrial workers to achieve a better standard of living. Netherlands Main article: Great Depression in the Netherlands From roughly 1931 to 1937, the Netherlands suffered a deep and exceptionally long depression. This depression was partly caused by the after-effects of the Stock Market Crash of 1929 in the U.S., and partly by internal factors in the Netherlands. Government policy, especially the very late dropping of the Gold Standard, played a role in prolonging the depression. The Great Depression in the Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and can be linked to the rise of the Dutch national-socialist party NSB. The depression in the Netherlands eased off somewhat at the end of 1936, when the government finally dropped the Gold Standard, but real economic stability did not return until after World War II.[126] New Zealand Main article: History of New Zealand § Great Depression New Zealand was especially vulnerable to worldwide depression, as it relied almost totally on agricultural exports to the United Kingdom for its economy. The drop in exports led to a lack of disposable income from the farmers, who were the mainstay of the local economy. Jobs disappeared and wages plummeted, leaving people desperate and charities unable to cope. Work relief schemes were the only government support available to the unemployed, the rate of which by the early 1930s was officially around 15%, but unofficially nearly twice that level (official figures excluded Māori and women). In 1932, riots occurred among the unemployed in three of the country's main cities (Auckland, Dunedin, and Wellington). Many were arrested or injured through the tough official handling of these riots by police and volunteer "special constables".[127] Portugal Main article: Economic history of Portugal Already under the rule of a dictatorial junta, the Ditadura Nacional, Portugal suffered no turbulent political effects of the Depression, although António de Oliveira Salazar, already appointed Minister of Finance in 1928 greatly expanded his powers and in 1932 rose to Prime Minister of Portugal to found the Estado Novo, an authoritarian corporatist dictatorship. With the budget balanced in 1929, the effects of the depression were relaxed through harsh measures towards budget balance and autarky, causing social discontent but stability and, eventually, an impressive economic growth.[128] Puerto Rico In the years immediately preceding the depression, negative developments in the island and world economies perpetuated an unsustainable cycle of subsistence for many Puerto Rican workers. The 1920s brought a dramatic drop in Puerto Rico’s two primary exports, raw sugar and coffee, due to a devastating hurricane in 1928 and the plummeting demand from global markets in the latter half of the decade. 1930 unemployment on the island was roughly 36% and by 1933 Puerto Rico’s per capita income dropped 30% (by comparison, unemployment in the United States in 1930 was approximately 8% reaching a height of 25% in 1933).[129][130] To provide relief and economic reform, the United States government and Puerto Rican politicians such as Carlos Chardon and Luis Munoz Marin created and administered first the Puerto Rico Emergency Relief Administration (PRERA) 1933 and then in 1935, the Puerto Rico Reconstruction Administration (PRRA).[131] South Africa Main article: Great Depression in South Africa As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. The Carnegie Commission on Poor Whites had concluded in 1931 that nearly one third of Afrikaners lived as paupers. The social discomfort caused by the depression was a contributing factor in the 1933 split between the "gesuiwerde" (purified) and "smelter" (fusionist) factions within the National Party and the National Party's subsequent fusion with the South African Party.[132][133] Soviet Union The Soviet Union was the world's sole communist state with very little international trade. Its economy was not tied to the rest of the world and was only slightly affected by the Great Depression.[134] Its forced transformation from a rural to an industrial society succeeded in building up heavy industry, at the cost of millions of lives in rural Russia and Ukraine.[135] At the time of the Depression, the Soviet economy was growing steadily, fuelled by intensive investment in heavy industry. The apparent economic success of the Soviet Union at a time when the capitalist world was in crisis led many Western intellectuals to view the Soviet system favorably. Jennifer Burns wrote: As the Great Depression ground on and unemployment soared, intellectuals began unfavorably comparing their faltering capitalist economy to Russian Communism. ... More than ten years after the Revolution, Communism was finally reaching full flower, according to New York Times reporter Walter Duranty, a Stalin fan who vigorously debunked accounts of the Ukraine famine, a man-made disaster that would leave millions dead."[136] Despite all of this, The Great Depression caused mass immigration to the Soviet Union, mostly from Finland and Germany. Soviet Russia was at first happy to help these immigrants settle, because they believed they were victims of capitalism who had come to help the Soviet cause. However, when the Soviet Union entered the war in 1941, most of these Germans and Finns were arrested and sent to Siberia, while their Russian-born children were placed in orphanages. Their fate is unknown.[137] Spain Main article: Economic history of Spain Spain had a relatively isolated economy, with high protective tariffs and was not one of the main countries affected by the Depression. The banking system held up well, as did agriculture.[138] By far the most serious negative impact came after 1936 from the heavy destruction of infrastructure and manpower by the civil war, 1936–39. Many talented workers were forced into permanent exile. By staying neutral in the Second World War, and selling to both sides, the economy avoided further disasters.[139] Sweden Main article: Economy of Sweden By the 1930s, Sweden had what America's Life magazine called in 1938 the "world's highest standard of living". Sweden was also the first country worldwide to recover completely from the Great Depression. Taking place in the midst of a short-lived government and a less-than-a-decade old Swedish democracy, events such as those surrounding Ivar Kreuger (who eventually committed suicide) remain infamous in Swedish history. Eventually, the Social Democrats under Per Albin Hansson would form their first long-lived government in 1932 based on strong interventionist and welfare state policies, monopolizing the office of Prime Minister until 1976 with the sole and short-lived exception of Axel Pehrsson-Bramstorp's "summer cabinet" in 1936. During forty years of hegemony, it was the most successful political party in the history of Western liberal democracy.[140] Thailand In Thailand, then known as the Kingdom of Siam, the Great Depression contributed to the end of the absolute monarchy of King Rama VII in the Siamese revolution of 1932. United Kingdom Main articles: Great Depression in the United Kingdom and Interwar Britain Unemployed people in front of a workhouse in London, 1930 The World Depression broke at a time when the United Kingdom was still far from having recovered from the effects of the First World War more than a decade earlier. The country was driven off the gold standard in 1931. The world financial crisis began to overwhelm Britain in 1931; investors across the world started withdrawing their gold from London at the rate of £2½ millions a day.[75] Credits of £25 millions each from the Bank of France and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15 millions fiduciary note slowed, but did not reverse the British crisis. The financial crisis now caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed; it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending and most controversially, to cut unemployment benefits 20%. The attack on welfare was totally unacceptable to the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but King George V insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "National Government". The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off the gold standard, and suffered relatively less than other major countries in the Grade Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was virtually destroyed, leaving MacDonald as Prime Minister for a largely Conservative coalition.[141][77] The effects on the northern industrial areas of Britain were immediate and devastating, as demand for traditional industrial products collapsed. By the end of 1930 unemployment had more than doubled from 1 million to 2.5 million (20% of the insured workforce), and exports had fallen in value by 50%. In 1933, 30% of Glaswegians were unemployed due to the severe decline in heavy industry. In some towns and cities in the north east, unemployment reached as high as 70% as shipbuilding fell 90%.[142] The National Hunger March of September–October 1932 was the largest[143] of a series of hunger marches in Britain in the 1920s and 1930s. About 200,000 unemployed men were sent to the work camps, which continued in operation until 1939.[144] In the less industrial Midlands and Southern England, the effects were short-lived and the later 1930s were a prosperous time. Growth in modern manufacture of electrical goods and a boom in the motor car industry was helped by a growing southern population and an expanding middle class. Agriculture also saw a boom during this period.[145] United States Main articles: Great Depression in the United States and New Deal Unemployed men queued outside a depression soup kitchen in Chicago 1931 Hoover's first measures to combat the depression were based on voluntarism by businesses not to reduce their workforce or cut wages. But businesses had little choice and wages were reduced, workers were laid off, and investments postponed.[146][147] In June 1930 Congress approved the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act which raised tariffs on thousands of imported items. The intent of the Act was to encourage the purchase of American-made products by increasing the cost of imported goods, while raising revenue for the federal government and protecting farmers. Other nations increased tariffs on American-made goods in retaliation, reducing international trade, and worsening the Depression.[148] In 1931 Hoover urged bankers to set up the National Credit Corporation[149] so that big banks could help failing banks survive. But bankers were reluctant to invest in failing banks, and the National Credit Corporation did almost nothing to address the problem.[150] Shacks on the Anacostia flats, Washington, D.C. put up by the Bonus Army (World War I veterans) burning after the battle with the 1,000 soldiers accompanied by tanks and machine guns, 1932[151] By 1932, unemployment had reached 23.6%, peaking in early 1933 at 25%.[152] Drought persisted in the agricultural heartland, businesses and families defaulted on record numbers of loans, and more than 5,000 banks had failed.[153] Hundreds of thousands of Americans found themselves homeless, and began congregating in shanty towns – dubbed "Hoovervilles" – that began to appear across the country.[154] In response, President Hoover and Congress approved the Federal Home Loan Bank Act, to spur new home construction, and reduce foreclosures. The final attempt of the Hoover Administration to stimulate the economy was the passage of the Emergency Relief and Construction Act (ERA) which included funds for public works programs such as dams and the creation of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation (RFC) in 1932. The Reconstruction Finance Corporation was a Federal agency with the authority to lend up to $2 billion to rescue banks and restore confidence in financial institutions. But $2 billion was not enough to save all the banks, and bank runs and bank failures continued.[146] Quarter by quarter the economy went downhill, as prices, profits and employment fell, leading to the political realignment in 1932 that brought to power Franklin Delano Roosevelt. It is important to note, however, that after volunteerism failed, Hoover developed ideas that laid the framework for parts of the New Deal. Buried machinery in a barn lot; South Dakota, May 1936. The Dust Bowl on the Great Plains coincided with the Great Depression.[155] Shortly after President Franklin Delano Roosevelt was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion combined to cause the Dust Bowl, shifting hundreds of thousands of displaced persons off their farms in the Midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt argued that restructuring of the economy would be needed to prevent another depression or avoid prolonging the current one. New Deal programs sought to stimulate demand and provide work and relief for the impoverished through increased government spending and the institution of financial reforms. During a "bank holiday" that lasted five days, the Emergency Banking Act was signed into law. It provided for a system of reopening sound banks under Treasury supervision, with federal loans available if needed. The Securities Act of 1933 comprehensively regulated the securities industry. This was followed by the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 which created the Securities and Exchange Commission. Though amended, key provisions of both Acts are still in force. Federal insurance of bank deposits was provided by the FDIC, and the Glass–Steagall Act. The Agricultural Adjustment Act provided incentives to cut farm production in order to raise farming prices. The National Recovery Administration (NRA) made a number of sweeping changes to the American economy. It forced businesses to work with government to set price codes through the NRA to fight deflationary "cut-throat competition" by the setting of minimum prices and wages, labor standards, and competitive conditions in all industries. It encouraged unions that would raise wages, to increase the purchasing power of the working class. The NRA was deemed unconstitutional by the Supreme Court of the United States in 1935. CCC workers constructing road, 1933. Over 3 million unemployed young men were taken out of the cities and placed into 2,600+ work camps managed by the CCC.[156] These reforms, together with several other relief and recovery measures, are called the First New Deal. Economic stimulus was attempted through a new alphabet soup of agencies set up in 1933 and 1934 and previously extant agencies such as the Reconstruction Finance Corporation. By 1935, the "Second New Deal" added Social Security (which was later considerably extended through the Fair Deal), a jobs program for the unemployed (the Works Progress Administration, WPA) and, through the National Labor Relations Board, a strong stimulus to the growth of labor unions. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted only 3% of the GDP. The national debt as a proportion of GNP rose under Hoover from 20% to 40%. Roosevelt kept it at 40% until the war began, when it soared to 128%. By 1936, the main economic indicators had regained the levels of the late 1920s, except for unemployment, which remained high at 11%, although this was considerably lower than the 25% unemployment rate seen in 1933. In the spring of 1937, American industrial production exceeded that of 1929 and remained level until June 1937. In June 1937, the Roosevelt administration cut spending and increased taxation in an attempt to balance the federal budget.[157] The American economy then took a sharp downturn, lasting for 13 months through most of 1938. Industrial production fell almost 30 per cent within a few months and production of durable goods fell even faster. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in 1938, rising from 5 million to more than 12 million in early 1938.[158] Manufacturing output fell by 37% from the 1937 peak and was back to 1934 levels.[159] WPA employed 2–3 million at unskilled labor Producers reduced their expenditures on durable goods, and inventories declined, but personal income was only 15% lower than it had been at the peak in 1937. As unemployment rose, consumers' expenditures declined, leading to further cutbacks in production. By May 1938 retail sales began to increase, employment improved, and industrial production turned up after June 1938.[160] After the recovery from the Recession of 1937–38, conservatives were able to form a bipartisan conservative coalition to stop further expansion of the New Deal and, when unemployment dropped to 2% in the early 1940s, they abolished WPA, CCC and the PWA relief programs. Social Security remained in place. Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt's critics charged that he was turning America into a socialist state.[161] The Great Depression was a main factor in the implementation of social democracy and planned economies in European countries after World War II (see Marshall Plan). Keynesianism generally remained the most influential economic school in the United States and in parts of Europe until the periods between the 1970s and the 1980s, when Milton Friedman and other neoliberal economists formulated and propagated the newly created theories of neoliberalism and incorporated them into the Chicago School of Economics as an alternative approach to the study of economics. Neoliberalism went on to challenge the dominance of the Keynesian school of Economics in the mainstream academia and policy-making in the United States, having reached its peak in popularity in the election of the presidency of Ronald Reagan in the United States, and Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom.[162]


Literature And the great owners, who must lose their land in an upheaval, the great owners with access to history, with eyes to read history and to know the great fact: when property accumulates in too few hands it is taken away. And that companion fact: when a majority of the people are hungry and cold they will take by force what they need. And the little screaming fact that sounds through all history: repression works only to strengthen and knit the repressed. –John Steinbeck, The Grapes of Wrath[163] The Great Depression has been the subject of much writing, as authors have sought to evaluate an era that caused both financial and emotional trauma. Perhaps the most noteworthy and famous novel written on the subject is The Grapes of Wrath, published in 1939 and written by John Steinbeck, who was awarded both the Nobel Prize for literature and the Pulitzer Prize for the work. The novel focuses on a poor family of sharecroppers who are forced from their home as drought, economic hardship, and changes in the agricultural industry occur during the Great Depression. Steinbeck's Of Mice and Men is another important novella about a journey during the Great Depression. Additionally, Harper Lee's To Kill a Mockingbird is set during the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood's Booker prize-winning The Blind Assassin is likewise set in the Great Depression, centering on a privileged socialite's love affair with a Marxist revolutionary. The era spurred the resurgence of social realism, practiced by many who started their writing careers on relief programs, especially the Federal Writers' Project in the U.S.[164][165][166][167] A number of works for younger audiences are also set during the Great Depression, among them the Kit Kittredge series of American Girl books written by Valerie Tripp and illustrated by Walter Rane, released to tie in with the dolls and playsets sold by the company. The stories, which take place during the early to mid 1930s in Cincinnati, focuses on the changes brought by the Depression to the titular character's family and how the Kittredges dealt with it.[168] A theatrical adaptation of the series entitled Kit Kittredge: An American Girl was later released in 2008 to positive reviews.[169][170] Similarly, Christmas After All, part of the Dear America series of books for older girls, take place in 1930s Indianapolis; while Kit Kittredge is told in a third-person viewpoint, Christmas After All is in the form of a fictional journal as told by the protagonist Minnie Swift as she recounts her experiences during the era, especially when her family takes in an orphan cousin from Texas.[171]


Naming Further information: Depression (economics) The term "The Great Depression" is most frequently attributed to British economist Lionel Robbins, whose 1934 book The Great Depression is credited with formalizing the phrase,[172] though Hoover is widely credited with popularizing the term,[172][173] informally referring to the downturn as a depression, with such uses as "Economic depression cannot be cured by legislative action or executive pronouncement" (December 1930, Message to Congress), and "I need not recount to you that the world is passing through a great depression" (1931). Black Friday, 9 May 1873, Vienna Stock Exchange. The Panic of 1873 and Long Depression followed. The term "depression" to refer to an economic downturn dates to the 19th century, when it was used by varied Americans and British politicians and economists. Indeed, the first major American economic crisis, the Panic of 1819, was described by then-president James Monroe as "a depression",[172] and the most recent economic crisis, the Depression of 1920–21, had been referred to as a "depression" by then-president Calvin Coolidge. Financial crises were traditionally referred to as "panics", most recently the major Panic of 1907, and the minor Panic of 1910–11, though the 1929 crisis was called "The Crash", and the term "panic" has since fallen out of use. At the time of the Great Depression, the term "The Great Depression" was already used to referred to the period 1873–96 (in the United Kingdom), or more narrowly 1873–79 (in the United States), which has retroactively been renamed the Long Depression.[174] Other "great depressions" Other economic downturns have been called a "great depression", but none had been as widespread, or lasted for so long. Various nations have experienced brief or extended periods of economic downturns, which were referred to as "depressions", but none have had such a widespread global impact.[citation needed] The collapse of the Soviet Union, and the breakdown of economic ties which followed, led to a severe economic crisis and catastrophic fall in the standards of living in the 1990s in post-Soviet states and the former Eastern Bloc,[175] which was even worse than the Great Depression.[176][177] Even before Russia's financial crisis of 1998, Russia's GDP was half of what it had been in the early 1990s,[177] and some populations are still poorer as of 2009[update] than they were in 1989, including Moldova, Central Asia, and the Caucasus.[citation needed]


Comparison with the Great Recession This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (May 2016) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Main article: Comparisons between the Great Recession and the Great Depression Some journalists and economists have taken to calling the late-2000s recession the "Great Recession" in allusion to the Great Depression.[178][179][180][181] The causes of the Great Recession seem similar to the Great Depression, but significant differences exist. The previous chairman of the Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke, had extensively studied the Great Depression as part of his doctoral work at MIT, and implemented policies to manipulate the money supply and interest rates in ways that were not done in the 1930s. Bernanke's policies will undoubtedly be analyzed and scrutinized in the years to come, as economists debate the wisdom of his choices. Generally speaking, the recovery of the world's financial systems tended to be quicker during the Great Depression of the 1930s as opposed to the late-2000s recession. If we contrast the 1930s with the Crash of 2008 where gold went through the roof, it is clear that the U.S. dollar on the gold standard was a completely different animal in comparison to the fiat free-floating U.S. dollar currency we have today. Both currencies in 1929 and 2008 were the U.S. dollar, but in an analogous way it is as if one was a Saber-toothed tiger and the other is a Bengal tiger; they are two completely different animals. Where we have experienced inflation since the Crash of 2008, the situation was much different in the 1930s when deflation set in. Unlike the deflation of the early 1930s, the U.S. economy currently appears to be in a "liquidity trap," or a situation where monetary policy is unable to stimulate an economy back to health. In terms of the stock market, nearly three years after the 1929 crash, the DJIA dropped 8.4% on August 12, 1932. Where we have experienced great volatility with large intraday swings in the past two months, in 2011, we have not experienced any record-shattering daily percentage drops to the tune of the 1930s. Where many of us may have that '30s feeling, in light of the DJIA, the CPI, and the national unemployment rate, we are simply not living in the '30s. Some individuals may feel as if we are living in a depression, but for many others the current global financial crisis simply does not feel like a depression akin to the 1930s.[182] 1928 and 1929 were the times in the 20th century that the wealth gap reached such skewed extremes;[183] half the unemployed had been out of work for over six months, something that was not repeated until the late-2000s recession. 2007 and 2008 eventually saw the world reach new levels of wealth gap inequality that rivalled the years of 1928 and 1929.


See also Book: Great Depression 1930s portal Causes of the Great Depression Cities in the Great Depression Dust Bowl Entertainment during the Great Depression Great Contraction List of Depression-era outlaws Timeline of the Great Depression General: Aftermath of World War I Economic collapse Involuntary unemployment List of economic crises


References ^ John A. Garraty, The Great Depression (1986) ^ Charles Duhigg, "Depression, You Say? Check Those Safety Nets", The New York Times, March 23, 2008. ^ Barry Eichengreen, Hall of Mirrors: The Great Depression, The Great Recession, and the Uses-and Misuses-of History (2014) ^ Roger Lowenstein, "History Repeating," Wall Street Journal Jan 14, 2015 ^ Garraty, Great Depression (1986) ch1 ^ a b Frank, Robert H.; Bernanke, Ben S. (2007). Principles of Macroeconomics (3rd ed.). Boston: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. p. 98. ISBN 0-07-319397-6.  ^ "Commodity Data". US Bureau of Labor Statistics. Retrieved 2008-11-30.  ^ Cochrane, Willard W. (1958). "Farm Prices, Myth and Reality": 15.  ^ "World Economic Survey 1932–33". League of Nations: 43.  ^ Mitchell, Depression Decade ^ a b c d Great Depression, Encyclopædia Britannica ^ "Economics focus: The Great Depression". The Economist.  ^ Schultz, Stanley K. (1999). "Crashing Hopes: The Great Depression". American History 102: Civil War to the Present. University of Wisconsin–Madison. Archived from the original on 2008-03-23. Retrieved 2008-03-13.  ^ "1998/99 Prognosis Based Upon 1929 Market Autopsy". Gold Eagle. Archived from the original on May 17, 2008. Retrieved 2008-05-22.  ^ "Drought: A Paleo Perspective – 20th Century Drought". National Climatic Data Center. Retrieved April 5, 2009.  ^ Hamilton, James (1987). "Monetary Factors in the Great Depression". Journal of Monetary Economics. 19 (2): 145–169. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(87)90045-6.  ^ Richard, Clay Hanes (editor) (July 2002). Historic Events for Students: The Great Depression (Volume I ed.). Gale. ISBN 978-0787657017. CS1 maint: Extra text: authors list (link) ^ Jerome Blum, Rondo Cameron, Thomas G. Barnes, The European world: a history (2nd ed 1970) page 885 ^ a b Robert Whaples, Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions., Journal of Economic History, Vol. 55, No. 1 (March 1995), p. 150 in JSTOR. ^ Robert Whaples, Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions., Journal of Economic History, Vol. 55, No. 1 (March 1995), p. 143 in JSTOR. ^ Klein, Lawrence R. (1947). "The Keynesian Revolution". New York: Macmillan: 56–58, 169, 177–79. ; Rosenof, Theodore (1997). Economics in the Long Run: New Deal Theorists and Their Legacies, 1933–1993. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 0-8078-2315-5.  ^ Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Edward Elgar Publishing, 2003, ISBN 9781843765509, p. 11-12 ^ A Monetary History of the United States.  ^ Bernanke, Ben S. (2000). Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. p. 7. ISBN 0-691-01698-4.  ^ "Bernanke: Federal Reserve caused Great Depression". WorldNetDaily. Retrieved 2008-03-21.  ^ Krugman, Paul (2007-02-15). "Who Was Milton Friedman?". The New York Review of Books. Archived from the original on April 10, 2008. Retrieved 2008-05-22.  ^ Griffin, G. Edward (2002). The Creature from Jekyll Island: A Second Look at the Federal Reserve. American Media. ISBN 978-0-912986-39-5.  ^ a b Freidel, Franklin D. Roosevelt: Launching the New Deal (1973) ch 19; text ^ a b J. Bradford De Long, "Liquidation" Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 3546, p. 1 ^ a b c Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Elgar publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-335-2, p. 9 ^ a b c White, Lawrence (2008). "Did Hayek and Robbins Deepen the Great Depression?". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 40 (40): 751–768. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2008.00134.x.  ^ J. Bradford De Long, "Liquidation" Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 3546, p. 5. ^ J. Bradford De Long, "Liquidation" Cycles: Old Fashioned Real Business Cycle Theory and the Great Depression, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 3546, p. 33. ^ a b c Fisher, Irving (October 1933). "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions". Econometrica. The Econometric Society. 1 (4): 337–357. doi:10.2307/1907327. JSTOR 1907327.  ^ Fortune, Peter (Sep–Oct 2000). "Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles – analysis of history of margin credit regulations – Statistical Data Included". New England Economic Review. Archived from the original on 2012-05-27.  ^ a b c "Bank Failures". Living History Farm. Retrieved 2008-05-22.  ^ "Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States", 352 ^ Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Edward Elgar Publishing, 2003, ISBN 9781843765509, p. 14-15 ^ Bernanke, Ben S (June 1983). "Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression". The American Economic Review. The American Economic Association. 73 (3): 257–276. JSTOR 1808111.  ^ Mishkin, Fredric (December 1978). "The Household Balance and the Great Depression". Journal of Economic History. 38 (4): 918–37. doi:10.1017/S0022050700087167.  ^ Gauti B. Eggertsson, Great Expectations and the End of the Depression, American Economic Review 2008, 98:4, 1476–1516 ^ Christina Romer, "The Fiscal Stimulus, Flawed but Valuable", The New York Times, October 20, 2012. ^ Peter Temin, Lessons from the Great Depression, MIT Press, 1992, ISBN 9780262261197, pp. 87–101. ^ Gauti B. Eggertsson, Great Expectations and the End of the Depression, The American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 4 (Sep., 2008), S. 1476–1516, p. 1480 ^ a b Murray Rothbard, America's Great Depression (Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2000), pp. 159–163. ^ Herman, Arthur, The Cave and the Light: Plato versus Aristotle, and the Struggle for the Soul of Western Civilization, p. 548 (Kindle location 10208). ^ Rothbard, America's Great Depression, pp. 19–21. ^ For Hayek's view, see Diego Pizano, Conversations with Great Economists: Friedrich A. Hayek, John Hicks, Nicholas Kaldor, Leonid V. Kantorovich, Joan Robinson, Paul A.Samuelson, Jan Tinbergen (Jorge Pinto Books, 2009). For Rothbard's view, see Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking in the United States (Ludwig von Mises Institute), pp. 293–294. ^ John Cunningham Wood, Robert D. Wood, Friedrich A. Hayek, Taylor & Francis, 2004, ISBN 9780415310574, p. 115 ^ Sennholz, Hans (October 1, 1969). "The Great Depression". Foundation for Economic Education. Retrieved October 23, 2016.  ^ Mises, Ludwig. "The Causes of the Economic Crisis, and Other Essays Before and After the Great Depression". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved October 24, 2016.  ^ Bonner, Bill (February 25, 2011). "Buying Bad Debt to Return Bank Solvency". Business Insider. Retrieved October 24, 2016.  ^ Harman, Chris (2009). Zombie Capitalism: Global Crisis and the Relevance of Marx. London: Bookmarks Publications. pp. 143–160. ISBN 978-1-905192-53-3.  ^ Dorfman 1959 ^ Allgoewer, Elisabeth (May 2002). "Underconsumption theories and Keynesian economics. Interpretations of the Great Depression" (PDF). Discussion paper no. 2002–14.  ^ The Road to Plenty (1928) ^ Hubbert, M. King (1940). "Man Hours and Distribution, Derived from Man Hours: A Declining Quantity, Technocracy, Series A, No. 8, August 1936".  ^ Bell, Spurgeon (1940). "Productivity, Wages and National Income, The Institute of Economics of the Brookings Institution".  ^ Peter Temin, Gianni Toniolo, The World Economy between the Wars, Oxford University Press, 2008, ISBN 9780198042013, p. 106 ^ Randall E. Parker, Reflections on the Great Depression, Elgar publishing, 2003, ISBN 978-1-84376-335-2, p. 22. ^ Robert Whaples: Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions. In: Journal of Economic History. Band 55, Nr. 1 (März 1995), S. 139–154, hier S. 151 in JSTOR. ^ International data from Maddison, Angus. "Historical Statistics for the World Economy: 1–2003 AD". [permanent dead link]. Gold dates culled from historical sources, principally Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-506431-3.  ^ Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-506431-3.  ^ Bernanke, Ben (March 2, 2004). "Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression". At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia.  ^ Robert Whaples, "Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions", Journal of Economic History, Vol. 55, No. 1 (Mar., 1995), pp. 139–54 in JSTOR ^ "The World in Depression". Mount Holyoke College. Archived from the original on March 10, 2008. Retrieved 2008-05-22.  ^ a b c d EICHENGREEN, B., & IRWIN, D. A. (2010). The Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who Succumbed and Why?. Journal of Economic History, 70(4), 871–97. ^ Whaples, Robert (March 1995). "Where Is There Consensus Among American Economic Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions" (PDF). The Journal of Economic History. Cambridge University Press. 55 (1): 144. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR 2123771 – via JSTOR. (Registration required (help)).  ^ Protectionism and the Great Depression, Paul Krugman, New York Times, November 30, 2009 ^ The protectionist temptation: Lessons from the Great Depression for today, VOX, Barry Eichengreen, Douglas Irwin, 17 March 2009 ^ Charles Loch Mowat, Britain between the wars, 1918–1940 (1955) pp 379–385. ^ a b William Ashworth, A short history of the international economy since 1850 (2nd ed 1962) pp 237–244. ^ a b Isabel Schnabel, "The German twin crisis of 1931." Journal of Economic History 64#3 (2004): 822–871. ^ a b H. V. Hodson, Slump and Recovery, 1929–1937 (London, 1938), pp. 64–76. ^ a b David Williams, "London and the 1931 financial crisis." Economic History Review 15.3 (1963): 513–528. ^ Mowat, Britain between the wars, 1918–1940 (1955) pp 386–412. ^ a b Sean Glynn and John Oxborrow, Interwar Britain : a social and economic history (1976) pp 67–73. ^ Per-capita GDP data from MeasuringWorth: What Was the U.S. GDP Then? ^ Gauti B. Eggertsson, "Great Expectations and the End of the Depression," American Economic Review 98, No. 4 (Sep 2008): 1476–1516; ^ "Was the New Deal Contractionary?" Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 264, Oct 2006, Gauti B. Eggertsson ^ "The Mistake of 1937: A General Equilibrium Analysis," Monetary and Economic Studies 24, No. S-1 (December 2006), Boj.or.jp ^ Gauti B. Eggertsson, "A Reply to Steven Horwitz's Commentary on 'Great Expectations and the End of the Great Depression,'" Econ Journal Watch 7(3), 197–204, September 2010 [1] ^ Steven Horwitz, "Unfortunately Unfamiliar with Robert Higgs and Others: A Rejoinder to Gauti Eggertsson on the 1930s," Econ Journal Watch 8(1), 2, January 2011. [2] ^ Romer, Christina D., "What Ended the Great Depression", Journal of Economic History, December 1992, vol. 52, no. 4, pp. 757–784 "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-01-17. Retrieved 2013-01-08.  "monetary development were crucial to the recovery implies that self-correction played little role in the growth of real output" ^ Ben Bernanke. Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-01698-6. p. 7 ^ Ben S. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propaga-tion of the Great Depression," The American Economic Review 73, No. 3 (June 1983): 257–76, available from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank collection at Stlouisfed.org ^ "Ben S. Bernanke, "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, No. 1 (February 1995): 1–28" (PDF). Fraser.stlouisfed.org. Retrieved 2014-10-16.  ^ W.S. Woytinsky and E.S. World population and production: trends and outlook (1953) p 148 ^ Denyse Baillargeon, Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal during the Great Depression (Wilfrid Laurier University Press, 1999), p. 159. ^ Jill Stephenson (2014). Women in Nazi Germany. Taylor & Francis. pp. 3–5. ISBN 9781317876076.  ^ Susan K. Foley (2004). Women in France Since 1789: The Meanings of Difference. Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 186–90. ISBN 9780230802148.  ^ Katrina Srigley (2010). Breadwinning Daughters: Young Working Women in a Depression-era City, 1929–1939. University of Toronto Press. p. 135. ISBN 9781442610033.  ^ Jessica S. Bean, "'To help keep the home going': female labour supply in interwar London." Economic History Review (2015) 68#2 pp 441–470. ^ Ann E. McCleary, "'I Was Really Proud of Them': Canned Raspberries and Home Production During the Farm Depression." Augusta Historical Bulletin (2010), Issue 46, pp 14–44. ^ Tari Klassen, "How Depression-Era Quiltmakers Constructed Domestic Space: An Interracial Processual Study," Midwestern Folklore: Journal of the Hoosier Folklore Society (2008) 34#2 pp 17–47. ^ Baillargeon, Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal during the Great Depression (1999), pp. 70, 108, 136–38, 159. ^ Mark Metzler, "Woman's Place in Japan's Great Depression: Reflections on the Moral Economy of Deflation." Journal of Japanese Studies (2004) 30#2 pp 315–352. ^ N. R. Reagin, "Marktordnung and Autarkic Housekeeping: Housewives and Private Consumption under the Four-Year Plan, 1936–1939," German History (2001) 19#2 pp 162–184. ^ Referring to the effect of World War II spending on the economy, economist John Kenneth Galbraith said, "One could not have had a better demonstration of the Keynesian ideas." Daniel Yergin, William Cran (writers / producer) (2002). Commanding Heights, see chapter 6 video or transcript (TV documentary). U.S.: PBS.  ^ Romer, Christina D. (1992). "What Ended the Great Depression?". Journal of Economic History. 52 (4): 757–784. doi:10.1017/S002205070001189X. fiscal policy was of little consequence even as late as 1942, suggests an interesting twist on the usual view that World War II caused, or at least accelerated, the recovery from the Great Depression.  ^ Higgs, Robert (1992-03-01). "Wartime Prosperity? A Reassessment of the U.S. Economy in the 1940s". The Journal of Economic History. 52 (1): 41–60. doi:10.1017/S0022050700010251. ISSN 1471-6372.  ^ Great Depression and World War II. The Library of Congress. ^ Depression & WWII Archived 2009-06-25 at the Wayback Machine.. Americaslibrary.gov. ^ Geoffrey Lawrence, Capitalism and the Countryside: The rural crisis in Australia (Pluto Press, 1987) ^ A Century of Change in the Australian Labour Market, Australian Bureau of Statistics ^ Judy Mackinolty, ed. The Wasted Years?: Australia's Great Depression (Allen & Unwin, 1981). ^ 1929–1939 – The Great Depression Archived 2009-01-27 at the Wayback Machine., Source: Bank of Canada ^ Henry Laufenburger, "France and the Depression," International Affairs (1936) 15#2 pp. 202–224 in JSTOR ^ Jean-Pierre Dormois, The French Economy in the Twentieth Century (2004) p 31 ^ Paul Beaudry and Franck Portier, "The French Depression in the 1930s," Review of Economic Dynamics (2002) 5:73–99 doi:10.1006/redy.2001.0143 ^ About the Great Depression, University of Illinois ^ Germany – Economic, Public Broadcasting Service (PBS). ^ "The History Place – Rise of Hitler: Hitler Runs for President". www.historyplace.com. Retrieved 2016-10-23.  ^ Adam Tooze, The Wages of Destruction: The Making and Breaking of the Nazi Economy (2007) ^ a b c Karlsson, Gunnar (2000). History of Iceland. pp. 308–312.  ^ Frank Barry and Mary F. Daly, "Concurrent Irish Perspectives on the Great Depression" (2010) [ online ] ^ Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly, "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" in Michael Psalidopoulos, The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012) pp. 395–424. ^ See also B. Girvin, Between Two Worlds: Politics and Economy in Independent Ireland (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1989). ^ Barry, Frank, and Mary E. Daly. "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" (No. iiisdp349. IIIS, 2011.) Online ^ Vera Zamagni, The economic history of Italy 1860–1990 (Oxford University Press, 1993) ^ Fabrizio Mattesini, and Beniamino Quintieri. "Italy and the Great Depression: An analysis of the Italian economy, 1929–1936." Explorations in Economic History (1997) 34#3 pp: 265–294. ^ Fabrizio Mattesini and Beniamino Quintieri. "Does a reduction in the length of the working week reduce unemployment? Some evidence from the Italian economy during the Great Depression." Explorations in Economic History (2006), 43#3, pp: 413–437. ^ Myung Soo Cha, "Did Takahashi Korekiyo Rescue Japan from the Great Depression?", The Journal of Economic History 63, No. 1 (March 2003): 127–144. ^ (For more on the Japanese economy in the 1930s see "MITI and the Japanese Miracle" by Chalmers Johnson) ^ Rosemary Thorp, Latin America in the 1930s: the role of the periphery in world crisis (Palgrave Macmillan, 2000). ^ E. H. Kossmann, The Low Countries: 1780–1940 (1978). ^ "Social Welfare and The State: Great Depression", Museum of New Zealand Te Papa Tongarewa. ^ José Cardozo, "The great depression and Portugal" in Michael Psalidopoulos, ed., The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012), ISBN 9789609979368. pp. 361–94 Online ^ Rodriguez, Manuel (2011). A New Deal for the Tropics. Princeton: Markus Wiener. p. 23.  ^ "Graph of U.S. Unemployment Rate: 1930–1945". American Social History Project. Retrieved April 19, 2017.  ^ Dietz, James (1986). Economic History of Puerto Rico. Princeton: Princeton University Press. pp. 154, 155.  ^ Dan O'Meara, Volkskapitalisme: class, capital, and ideology in the development of Afrikaner nationalism, 1934–1948 (Cambridge University Press, 1983). ^ The Great Depression and the 1930S, Federal Research Division of the Library of Congress. ^ Robert William Davies, Mark Harrison, and Stephen G. Wheatcroft, eds. The economic transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945 (Cambridge University Press, 1994) ^ Robert Conquest, The Harvest of Sorrow: Soviet Collectivization and the Terror-Famine (1987). ^ Jennifer Burns (2009). Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right, p. 34. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-532487-0 ^ http://www.genealogia.fi/emi/art/article237e.htm ^ Gabriel Tortella and Jordi Palafox, "Banking and Industry in Spain 1918–1936," Journal of European Economic History (1984), 13#2 Special Issue, pp. 81–110. ^ R. J. Harrison, Economic History of Modern Spain (1978), pp. 129–49. ^ Göran Therborn, "A Unique Chapter in the History of Democracy: The Swedish Social Democrats", in K. Misgeld et al (eds), Creating Social Democracy, University Park Pa., Penn State University Press, 1996. ^ Charles Loch Mowat, Britain between the wars, 1918–1940 (1955) pp 386–412. ^ Unemployment During The Great Depression Archived 2009-01-24 at the Wayback Machine., thegreatdepression.co.uk ^ Cook, Chris and Bewes, Diccon; What Happened Where: A Guide To Places And Events In Twentieth-Century History p. 115; Routledge, 1997 ISBN 1-85728-533-6 ^ "Work camps that tackled Depression", BBC News. ^ Constantine, Stephen (1983), Social Conditions in Britain 1918–1939, ISBN 0-416-36010-6 ^ a b Peter Clemens, Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal: The USA 1890–1954, Hodder Education, 4. Auflage, 2008, ISBN 978-0-340-965887, p. 114. ^ Charles R. Morris, A Rabble of Dead Money: The Great Crash and the Global Depression: 1929–1939 (PublicAffairs, 2017), 389 pp. online review ^ "Smoot-Hawley Tariff" Archived 2009-03-12 at the Wayback Machine., U.S. Department of State. ^ "Reconstruction Finance Corporation". EH.net Encyclopedia. Archived from the original on October 29, 2013.  ^ Clemens, Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal, 2008, p. 113. ^ The Great Depression (1929–1939), The Eleanor Roosevelt Papers. Archived December 23, 2008, at the Wayback Machine. ^ Swanson, Joseph; Williamson, Samuel (1972). "Estimates of national product and income for the United States economy, 1919–1941". Explorations in Economic History. 10: 53–73. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(72)90003-4.  ^ "Great Depression in the United States", Microsoft Encarta. Archived 2009-10-31. Archived March 1, 2009, at the Wayback Machine. ^ Joyce Bryant, "The Great Depression and New Deal", Yale-New Haven Teachers Institute. ^ The Dust Bowl, Geoff Cunfer, Southwest Minnesota State University. Archived December 28, 2008, at the Wayback Machine. ^ "National Park History: "The Spirit of the Civilian Conservation Corps"". Nationalparkstraveler.com. Retrieved September 4, 2010.  ^ Robert Goldston, The Great Depression, Fawcett Publications, 1968, p. 228. ^ Economic Fluctuations, Maurice W. Lee, Chairman of Economics Dept., Washington State College, published by R. D. Irwin Inc, Homewood, Illinois, 1955, p. 236. ^ Business Cycles, James Arthur Estey, Purdue University, Prentice-Hall, 1950, pp. 22–23 chart. ^ Maurice W. Lee, 1955. ^ Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Coming of the New Deal: 1933–1935. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003. (First published in 1958) ISBN 0-618-34086-6; Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Politics of Upheaval: 1935–1936. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003. (First published in 1960) ISBN 0-618-34087-4 ^ Lanny Ebenstein, Milton Friedman: A Biography (2007). ^ The Grapes of Wrath, by John Steinbeck, Penguin, 2006, 0143039431, p. 238 ^ David Taylor, Soul of a People: The WPA Writers' Project Uncovers Depression America (2009). ^ Jerre Mangione, The Dream and the Deal: The Federal Writers' Project, 1935–1943 (1996) ^ Jerrold Hirsch, Portrait of America: A Cultural History of the Federal Writers' Project (2006) ^ Stacy I. Morgan, Rethinking Social Realism: African American art and literature, 1930–1953 (2004), p. 244. ^ Harry, Lou (1 October 2010). Cincinnati Magazine. Emmis Communications. pp. 59–63. Retrieved 10 July 2017.  ^ Morency, Philip. On the Aisle, Volume 2: Film Reviews by Philip Morency. Dorrance Publishing. pp. 133–. ISBN 9781434977090.  ^ Pimpare, Stephen (2017). Ghettos, Tramps, and Welfare Queens: Down and Out on the Silver Screen. Oxford University Press. pp. 216–. ISBN 9780190660727. Retrieved 10 July 2017.  ^ Smith, Robert W. (2006-01-26). Spotlight on America: The Great Depression. Teacher Created Resources. ISBN 9781420632187. Retrieved 10 July 2017.  ^ a b c When Did the Great Depression Receive Its Name? (And Who Named It?), 2-16-09, by Noah Mendel, History News Network ^ William Manchester, The Glory and the Dream: A Narrative History of America, 1932–1972. ^ Fletcher, T. W. (1961). "The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873–1896". The Economic History Review. Blackwell Publishing. 13 (3): 417–432. doi:10.2307/2599512. JSTOR 2599512.  ^ "Child poverty soars in eastern Europe", BBC News, October 11, 2000. ^ See "What Can Transition Economies Learn from the First Ten Years? A New World Bank Report," in Transition Newsletter Worldbank.org[dead link], K-A.kg ^ a b Who Lost Russia?, New York Times, October 8, 2000. ^ Rampell, Catherine (March 11, 2009). "'Great Recession': A Brief Etymology". The New York Times.  ^ Gibbs, Nancy (April 15, 2009). "The Great Recession: America Becomes Thrift Nation". Time.  ^ Krugman, Paul (March 20, 2009). "The Great Recession versus the Great Depression". The New York Times.  ^ Lahart, Justin (July 28, 2009). "The Great Recession: A Downturn Sized Up". The Wall Street Journal.  ^ Rabinowitz, Marco (October 6, 2011). "The Great Depression vs. the Great Recession: A look at the value of the U.S. dollar in 1929 and 2008; what has changed and where that leaves us today". MSN Money. Benzinga. ^ Evans-Pritchard, Ambrose (September 14, 2010). "IMF Fears 'Social Explosion' From World Jobs Crisis". The Daily Telegraph (London). "America and Europe face the worst jobs crisis since the 1930s and risk 'an explosion of social unrest' unless they tread carefully, the International Monetary Fund has warned."


Further reading Ambrosius, G., and W. Hibbard, A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe (1989) Bernanke, Ben (1995). "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. Blackwell Publishing. 27 (1): 1–28. doi:10.2307/2077848. JSTOR 2077848.  Brown, Ian. The Economies of Africa and Asia in the Iinter-war Depression (1989) Davis, Joseph S. The World Between the Wars, 1919–39: An Economist's View (1974) Drinot, Paulo, and Alan Knight, eds. The Great Depression in Latin America (2014) excerpt Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The gold standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. 1992. Eichengreen, Barry, and Marc Flandreau. The Gold Standard in Theory and History (1997) online version Feinstein. Charles H. The European Economy between the Wars (1997) Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 (1963), monetarist interpretation (heavily statistical) Galbraith, John Kenneth, The Great Crash, 1929 (1954), popular Garraty, John A. The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History (1986) Garraty John A. Unemployment in History (1978) Garside, William R. Capitalism in Crisis: international responses to the Great Depression (1993) Glasner, David, ed. Business Cycles and Depressions (Routledge, 1997), 800pp; Excerpt Goldston, Robert, The Great Depression: The United States in the Thirties (1968) Grinin, L., Korotayev, A. and Tausch A. (2016) Economic Cycles, Crises, and the Global Periphery. Springer International Publishing, Heidelberg, New York, Dordrecht, London, ISBN 978-3-319-17780-9; https://www.springer.com/de/book/9783319412603 Haberler, Gottfried. The World Economy, money, and the great depression 1919–1939 (1976) Hall Thomas E., and J. David Ferguson. The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies (1998) Hodson, H. V. Slump and Recovery, 1929–37 (Oxford UP, 1938). online 496pp; annual histories Kaiser, David E. Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930–1939 (1980) Kehoe, Timothy J., and Edward C. Prescott, eds. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century (2007), essays by economists on U.S., Britain, France, Germany, Italy and on tariffs; statistical Kindleberger, Charles P. The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (3rd ed. 2013) Konrad, Helmut and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. Routes Into the Abyss: Coping With Crises in the 1930s (Berghahn Books, 2013), 224 pp. Compares Germany, Italy, Austria, and Spain with those in Sweden, Japan, China, India, Turkey, Brazil, and the United States. Madsen, Jakob B. "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression", Southern Economic Journal, Southern Economic Journal (2001) 67#4 pp:848–868 online at JSTOR. Markwell, Donald. John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace, Oxford University Press (2006). Mitchell, Broadus. Depression Decade: From New Era through New Deal, 1929–1941 (1947), 462pp; thorough coverage of the U.S.. economy Mundell, R. A. "A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century", The American Economic Review Vol. 90, No. 3 (Jun., 2000), pp. 327–340 online version Psalidopoulos, Michael, ed. The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012). ISBN 9789609979368. Chapters by economic historians cover Finland, Sweden, Belgium, Austria, Italy, Greece, Turkey, Bulgaria, Yugoslavia, Romania, Spain, Portugal, and Ireland. table of contents Romer, Christina D. "The Nation in Depression," Journal of Economic Perspectives (1993) 7#2 pp. 19–39 in JSTOR, statistical comparison of U.S. and other countries Rothermund, Dietmar. The Global Impact of the Great Depression (1996) Online Tipton, F., and R. Aldrich, An Economic and Social History of Europe, 1890–1939 (1987) For U.S. specific references, please see the listing in Great Depression in the United States. Contemporary Keynes, John Maynard. "The World's Economic Outlook", Atlantic (May 1932), online edition. Schumpeter, Joseph (1930). "The Present World Depression: A Tentative Diagnosis". Available on JSTOR. League of Nations, World Economic Survey 1932–33 (1934).


External links Wikimedia Commons has media related to Great Depression. Wikiquote has quotations related to: Great Depression Rare Color Photos from the Great Depression – slideshow by The Huffington Post EH.net, "An Overview of the Great Depression", by Randall Parker. America in the 1930s. Extensive library of projects on America in the Great Depression from American Studies at the University of Virginia The 1930s Timeline, year by year timeline of events in science and technology, politics and society, culture and international events with embedded audio and video. AS@UVA Great Myths of the Great Depression by Lawrence Reed Franklin D. Roosevelt Library & Museum for copyright-free photos of the period An Age of Lost Innocence: Childhood Realities and Adult Fears in the Depression. American Studies at the University of Virginia Great Depression in the Deep South Soul of a People documentary on Smithsonian Networks The Great Depression at the History Channel "Chairman Ben Bernanke Lecture Series Part 1".Recorded live on March 20, 2012 10:35am MST at a class at George Washington University v t e Great Depression Topics Causes Wall Street Crash of 1929 Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act Dust Bowl New Deal Recession of 1937–1938 Effects by area Australia Canada Chile Central Europe France Germany India Japan Latin America Netherlands South Africa United Kingdom United States Cities Category Commons v t e New Deal Causes and legacy Great Depression New Deal Coalition Brain Trust American Liberty League Criticism New Deal Emergency Banking Act Economy Act Agricultural Adjustment Act Civilian Conservation Corps (CCC) Civil Works Administration Communications Act Executive Order 6102 Homeowners Refinancing Act Farm Credit Administration Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) Federal Emergency Relief Administration Frazier–Lemke Farm Bankruptcy Act Glass–Steagall Act National Industrial Recovery Act National Housing Act National Recovery Administration National Youth Administration Public Works Administration (PWA) Public Works of Art Project Reciprocal Tariff Act Railroad Retirement Act Securities Act Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) Second New Deal Works Progress Administration (WPA) Federal Project Number One Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Farm Security Administration Judicial Procedures Reform Act National Bituminous Coal Conservation Act National Labor Relations Board (Act) Rural Electrification Act Rural Electrification Administration Social Security United States Housing Authority Individuals Franklin D. Roosevelt Harold L. Ickes Frances Perkins Harry Hopkins Henry Morgenthau, Jr. Huey Long Herbert Hoover Robert F. Wagner Category Commons v t e Recessions in the United States (notable recessions in bold) 1796–99 1815–21 1836–38 and 1839–43 1857–58 1873–1879 1882–85 1893–1897 1907–08 1918–19 1920–21 1929–33 and 1937–38 1949 1953–54 1958 1960–61 1969–70 1973–75 1980 and 1981–82 1990–91 2002–03 2007–09 v t e United States articles History By event Timeline of U.S. history Pre-Columbian era Colonial era Thirteen Colonies military history Continental Congress American Revolution War American frontier America's Critical Period Drafting and ratification of Constitution Federalist Era War of 1812 Territorial acquisitions Territorial evolution Mexican–American War Civil War Reconstruction Era Indian Wars Gilded Age Progressive Era African-American civil rights movement 1865–1896 / 1896–1954 / 1954–1968 Spanish–American War Imperialism World War I Roaring Twenties Great Depression World War II home front Nazism in the United States American Century Cold War Korean War Space Race Feminist Movement Vietnam War Post-Cold War (1991–2008) War on Terror War in Afghanistan Iraq War Recent events (2008–present) By topic Outline of U.S. history Demographic Discoveries Economic debt ceiling Inventions before 1890 1890–1945 1946–91 after 1991 Military Postal Technological and industrial Geography Territory counties federal district federal enclaves Indian reservations insular zones minor outlying islands populated places states Earthquakes Extreme points Islands Mountains peaks ranges Appalachian Rocky National Park Service National Parks Regions East Coast West Coast Great Plains Gulf Mid-Atlantic Midwestern New England Pacific Central Eastern Northern Northeastern Northwestern Southern Southeastern Southwestern Western Rivers Colorado Columbia Mississippi Missouri Ohio Rio Grande Yukon Time Water supply and sanitation Politics Federal Executive Cabinet Civil service Executive departments Executive Office Independent agencies Law enforcement President of the United States Public policy Legislative House of Representatives current members Speaker Senate current members President pro tempore Vice President Judicial Courts of appeals District courts Supreme Court Law Bill of Rights civil liberties Code of Federal Regulations Constitution federalism preemption separation of powers Federal Reporter United States Code United States Reports Intelligence Central Intelligence Agency Defense Intelligence Agency Federal Bureau of Investigation National Geospatial-Intelligence Agency National Reconnaissance Office National Security Agency Office of the Director of National Intelligence Uniformed Armed Forces Army Marine Corps Navy Air Force Coast Guard National Guard NOAA Corps Public Health Service Corps 51st state political status of Puerto Rico District of Columbia statehood movement Elections Electoral College Foreign relations Foreign policy Hawaiian sovereignty movement Ideologies anti-Americanism exceptionalism nationalism Local government Parties Democratic Republican Third parties Red states and blue states Purple America Scandals State government governor state legislature state court Uncle Sam Economy By sector Agriculture Banking Communications Energy Insurance Manufacturing Mining Tourism Trade Transportation Companies by state Currency Exports Federal budget Federal Reserve System Financial position Labor unions Public debt Social welfare programs Taxation Unemployment Wall Street Society Culture Americana Architecture Cinema Cuisine Dance Demography Education Family structure Fashion Flag Folklore Languages American English Indigenous languages ASL Black American Sign Language HSL Plains Sign Talk Arabic Chinese French German Italian Russian Spanish Literature Media Journalism Internet Newspapers Radio Television Music Names People Philosophy Public holidays Religion Sexuality Sports Theater Visual art Social class Affluence American Dream Educational attainment Homelessness Home-ownership Household income Income inequality Middle class Personal income Poverty Professional and working class conflict Standard of living Wealth Issues Ages of consent Capital punishment Crime incarceration Criticism of government Discrimination affirmative action antisemitism intersex rights islamophobia LGBT rights racism same-sex marriage Drug policy Energy policy Environmental movement Gun politics Health care abortion health insurance hunger obesity smoking Human rights Immigration illegal International rankings National security Mass surveillance Terrorism Separation of church and state Outline Index Book Category Portal v t e Economics Economic theory Econometrics Applied economics Macroeconomics Adaptive expectations Aggregate demand Balance of payments Business cycle Capacity utilization Capital flight Central bank Consumer confidence Currency Demand shock Depression (Great Depression) DSGE Economic growth Economic indicator Economic rent Effective demand General Theory of Keynes Hyperinflation Inflation Interest Interest rate Investment IS–LM model Microfoundations Monetary policy Money NAIRU National accounts PPP Rate of profit Rational expectations Recession Saving Shrinkflation Stagflation Supply shock Unemployment Macroeconomics publications Microeconomics Aggregation problem Budget set Consumer choice Convexity Cost–benefit analysis Deadweight loss Distribution Duopoly Economic equilibrium Economic shortage Economic surplus Economies of scale Economies of scope Elasticity Expected utility hypothesis Externality General equilibrium theory Indifference curve Intertemporal choice Marginal cost Market failure Market structure Monopoly Monopsony Non-convexity Oligopoly Opportunity cost Preference Production set Profit Public good Returns to scale Risk aversion Scarcity Social choice theory Sunk costs Supply and demand Theory of the firm Trade Transaction cost Value Uncertainty Utility Microeconomics publications Applied fields Agricultural Business Demographic Development Economic history Education Engineering Environmental Financial Health Industrial organization International Knowledge Labour Law and economics Monetary Natural resource Public Service Transportation Urban Welfare Methodology Behavioral economics Computational economics Econometrics Economic systems Experimental economics Mathematical economics Methodological publications Economic thought Ancient economic thought Austrian school of economics Chicago school of economics Classical economics Feminist economics Heterodox economics Institutional economics Keynesian economics Mainstream economics Marxian economics Neoclassical economics Post-Keynesian economics Schools overview Notable economists and thinkers within economics Kenneth Arrow Gary Becker Francis Ysidro Edgeworth Milton Friedman Ragnar Frisch Friedrich Hayek Harold Hotelling John Maynard Keynes Tjalling Koopmans Paul Krugman Robert Lucas Jr. Jacob Marschak Alfred Marshall Karl Marx John von Neumann Vilfredo Pareto David Ricardo Paul Samuelson Joseph Schumpeter Amartya Sen Herbert A. Simon Adam Smith Robert Solow Léon Walras more International organizations Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation Economic Cooperation Organization European Free Trade Association International Monetary Fund Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development World Bank World Trade Organization Category Index Lists Outline Publications Business and economics portal v t e Employment Classifications Casual Contingent Full-time Part-time Self-employed Skilled Independent contractor Temporary Tenure Unskilled Wage labour Hiring Application Background check Business networking Contract Cover letter Curriculum Vitae (CV) Drug testing e-recruitment Employment counsellor Executive search Induction programme Job fair Job fraud Job hunting Job interview Labour brokering Overqualification Onboarding Personality-job fit theory Person-environment fit Probation Reference Résumé Simultaneous recruiting of new graduates Underemployment Work-at-home scheme Roles Co-op Employee Employer Internship Job Permanent Permatemp Supervisor Volunteer Worker class Blue-collar Gold-collar Green-collar Grey-collar Pink-collar White-collar Career and training Apprenticeship Avocation Career assessment Career counseling Career development Coaching Creative class Education Continuing education Continuing professional development E-learning Employability Further education Graduate school Induction training Initial Professional Development Knowledge worker Licensure Lifelong learning Practice-based professional learning Professional association Professional certification Professional development Professional school Reflective practice Retraining Vocational education Vocational school Vocational university Mentorship Occupational Outlook Handbook Practice firm Profession Tradesman Vocation Attendance Break Career break Furlough Gap year Leave of absence Long service leave No call, no show Sabbatical Sick leave Time clock Schedules Four-day week Eight-hour day Flextime Overtime Retroactive overtime Shift work Telecommuting Working time Workweek and weekend Wages and salaries Income bracket Income tax Living wage Maximum wage National average salary World Europe Minimum wage Canada Hong Kong Europe United States Progressive wage Singapore Overtime rate Paid time off Performance-related pay Salary Salary cap Working poor Benefits Annual leave Casual Friday Day care Disability insurance Health insurance Life insurance Parental leave Pension Sick leave Take-home vehicle Safety and health Epilepsy and employment Human factors and ergonomics Industrial noise Karōshi Protective clothing Occupational burnout Occupational disease Occupational exposure limit Occupational health psychology Occupational injury Occupational stress Repetitive strain injury Sick building syndrome Work accident Occupational fatality Workers' compensation Workplace phobia Workplace wellness Equality Affirmative action Equal pay for women Gender pay gap Glass ceiling Infractions Corporate abuse Accounting scandals Corporate behaviour Corporate crime Control fraud Corporate scandals Discrimination Dress code Employee handbook Employee monitoring Evaluation Labour law Sexual harassment Sleeping while on duty Wage theft Whistleblower Workplace bullying Workplace harassment Workplace incivility Willingness Boreout Civil conscription Conscription Dead-end job Extreme careerism Job satisfaction Organizational commitment McJob Refusal of work Slavery Bonded labour Human trafficking Labour camp Penal labour Peonage Truck system Unfree labour Wage slavery Workaholic Work aversion Work ethic Work–life balance Downshifting Slow living Termination At-will employment Dismissal Banishment room Constructive dismissal Wrongful dismissal Employee exit management Exit interview Layoff Notice period Pink slip Resignation Letter of resignation Restructuring Retirement Mandatory retirement Retirement age Severance package Golden handshake Golden parachute Turnover Unemployment Barriers to Employment Depression Great Depression Long Depression Discouraged worker Frictional unemployment Full employment Graduate unemployment Involuntary unemployment Jobless recovery Phillips curve Recession Great Recession Great Recession job losses List of recessions Recession-proof job Reserve army of labour Types of unemployment Unemployment Convention Unemployment benefits Unemployment extension Unemployment insurance Unemployment rates Employment rates Employment-to-population ratio Structural unemployment Technological unemployment Wage curve Youth unemployment See also templates Aspects of corporations Aspects of jobs Aspects of occupations Aspects of organizations Aspects of workplaces Corporate titles Organized labor Authority control LCCN: sh85037058 GND: 4079171-3 Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Great_Depression&oldid=819863165" Categories: Great Depression1920s economic history1930s economic historyFinancial crisesWorld economyHidden categories: CS1 maint: Extra text: authors listAll articles with dead external linksArticles with dead external links from May 2017Articles with permanently dead external linksPages with login required references or sourcesWebarchive template wayback linksArticles with dead external links from January 2016Wikipedia pages semi-protected against vandalismAll articles with unsourced statementsArticles with unsourced statements from June 2016Articles with unsourced statements from May 2016Articles needing additional references from May 2016All articles needing additional referencesArticles to be split from September 2017All articles to be splitArticles with unsourced statements from February 2012Articles containing potentially dated statements from 2009All articles containing potentially dated statementsArticles with unsourced statements from October 2015Wikipedia articles with LCCN identifiersWikipedia articles with GND identifiers


Navigation menu Personal tools Not logged inTalkContributionsCreate accountLog in Namespaces ArticleTalk Variants Views ReadView sourceView history More Search Navigation Main pageContentsFeatured contentCurrent eventsRandom articleDonate to WikipediaWikipedia store Interaction HelpAbout WikipediaCommunity portalRecent changesContact page Tools What links hereRelated changesUpload fileSpecial pagesPermanent linkPage informationWikidata itemCite this page Print/export Create a bookDownload as PDFPrintable version In other projects Wikimedia CommonsWikiquote Languages AfrikaansAlemannischالعربيةAragonésAsturianuAzərbaycancaتۆرکجهবাংলাBân-lâm-gúБашҡортсаБеларускаяБеларуская (тарашкевіца)‎БългарскиBosanskiBrezhonegCatalàČeštinaCymraegDanskDeutschEestiΕλληνικάEspañolEsperantoEuskaraفارسیFiji HindiFrançaisFryskGaeilgeGalego한국어Հայերենहिन्दीHrvatskiIlokanoBahasa IndonesiaИронÍslenskaItalianoעבריתКъарачай-малкъарქართულიҚазақшаKiswahiliLatinaLatviešuLietuviųMagyarМакедонскиമലയാളംBahasa MelayuMirandésМонголမြန်မာဘာသာNederlandsनेपाल भाषा日本語NorskNorsk nynorskOccitanਪੰਜਾਬੀپنجابیپښتوPatoisPolskiPortuguêsRomânăРусиньскыйРусскийСаха тылаScotsSimple EnglishSlovenčinaSlovenščinaکوردیСрпски / srpskiSrpskohrvatski / српскохрватскиSuomiSvenskaTagalogதமிழ்Татарча/tatarçaไทยTürkçeУкраїнськаاردوTiếng ViệtVõroWinarayייִדיש粵語Žemaitėška中文 Edit links This page was last edited on 11 January 2018, at 18:10. Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization. Privacy policy About Wikipedia Disclaimers Contact Wikipedia Developers Cookie statement Mobile view (window.RLQ=window.RLQ||[]).push(function(){mw.config.set({"wgPageParseReport":{"limitreport":{"cputime":"1.280","walltime":"1.496","ppvisitednodes":{"value":11715,"limit":1000000},"ppgeneratednodes":{"value":0,"limit":1500000},"postexpandincludesize":{"value":443586,"limit":2097152},"templateargumentsize":{"value":60885,"limit":2097152},"expansiondepth":{"value":16,"limit":40},"expensivefunctioncount":{"value":33,"limit":500},"entityaccesscount":{"value":1,"limit":400},"timingprofile":["100.00% 1167.726 1 -total"," 46.06% 537.862 1 Template:Reflist"," 12.43% 145.141 14 Template:Navbox"," 11.40% 133.086 19 Template:Cite_book"," 8.83% 103.160 8 Template:Citation_needed"," 8.31% 97.035 10 Template:Fix"," 8.10% 94.537 20 Template:Cite_journal"," 7.32% 85.468 17 Template:ISBN"," 7.23% 84.432 1 Template:United_States_topics"," 6.91% 80.640 1 Template:Country_topics"]},"scribunto":{"limitreport-timeusage":{"value":"0.527","limit":"10.000"},"limitreport-memusage":{"value":7700567,"limit":52428800}},"cachereport":{"origin":"mw1319","timestamp":"20180115101747","ttl":1900800,"transientcontent":false}}});});(window.RLQ=window.RLQ||[]).push(function(){mw.config.set({"wgBackendResponseTime":1635,"wgHostname":"mw1319"});});


Great_Depression - Photos and All Basic Informations

Great_Depression More Links

This Article Is Semi-protected Due To VandalismThe Great Depression (disambiguation)The Great Slump (disambiguation)EnlargeDorothea LangeMigrant MotherPea-pickersCaliforniaFlorence Owens ThompsonNipomo, CaliforniaEnlargeEnlargeDepression (economics)United StatesStock Market CrashWall Street Crash Of 1929Gross Domestic ProductGreat RecessionWorld War IIDeveloped CountryDeveloping CountryPersonal IncomeCities In The Great DepressionHeavy IndustryPrimary Sector Of The EconomyTimeline Of The Great DepressionEnlargeDow Jones Industrial AverageBlack TuesdayJohn D. RockefellerDust BowlEnlargeSoup KitchenAl CaponeChicagoIllinoisDeflationDeflationary SpiralWikipedia:Citation NeededEconomy Of The United StatesProtectionismSmoot–Hawley Tariff ActWikipedia:Citation NeededCauses Of The Great DepressionEnlargeBlack TuesdayEmergency Banking ActBank RunsEnlargeWall StreetWall Street Crash Of 1929EnlargeKeynesian EconomicsMonetarismHeterodox EconomicsMilton FriedmanFederal Reserve SystemJohn Maynard KeynesThe General Theory Of Employment, Interest And MoneyAggregate ExpenditureCrisis (economic)Government SpendingFranklin D. RooseveltPublic WorksAgricultural SubsidyWorld War IIEnlargeReal Gross Domestic ProductPrice IndexMoney SupplyEnlargeBank RunMilton FriedmanAnna J. SchwartzContractionary Monetary PolicyDeflationNew York Bank Of United StatesGovernment BondOpen MarketGold StandardFederal Reserve ActExecutive Order 6102Gold CertificateMoney SupplyAggregate DemandCentral BankSay's LawLiquidationismHerbert HooverBarry EichengreenJ. Bradford DeLongAndrew MellonOlivier BlanchardLawrence SummersCapital AccumulationEnlargeBank Of United StatesEnlargeIrving FisherPessimismMargin CallBank RunEmergency Banking ActInvestmentVirtuous Circle And Vicious CircleMilton FriedmanAnna SchwartzBen BernankeAggregate DemandCredit CrunchNew Neoclassical SynthesisPeter TeminChristina RomerFranklin D. RooseveltRecession Of 1937–38Friedrich HayekMurray RothbardAmerica's Great DepressionMoney SupplyCapital GoodsHans SennholzAustrian Business Cycle TheoryCalvin CoolidgeSixteenth Amendment To The United States ConstitutionThe Federal Reserve ActHawley-Smoot Tariff ActRevenue Act Of 1932Ludwig Von MisesKarl MarxMarxismCapitalismCrisis (Marxian)Boom And BustSocial ProgressEnlargeMechanised AgricultureChildress County, TexasWaddill CatchingsWilliam Trufant FosterHenry A. WallacePaul DouglasMarriner EcclesDistribution Of WealthRoot CauseConsumer SpendingM. King HubbertElectrificationMass ProductionWikipedia:Citation NeededProductivityWikipedia:VerifiabilityHelp:Introduction To Referencing With Wiki Markup/1Help:Maintenance Template RemovalPrice–specie Flow MechanismDeflationSmoot–Hawley Tariff ActEnlargeGold StandardSpeculative AttackPound SterlingOfficial Gold ReservesBank Of EnglandSilver StandardDeveloping CountrySmoot–Hawley Tariff ActAd ValoremBalance Of PaymentsCurrency Appreciation And DepreciationGold StandardSmoot–Hawley Tariff ActWikipedia:SplittingEuropean Banking Crisis Of 1931Talk:Great DepressionCreditanstaltHoover MoratoriumAdolf Hitler's Rise To PowerNational Government (United Kingdom)Gold StandardEnlargeUnemployment RateUnderemploymentLabour EconomicsWikipedia:Citation NeededNew DealReflationWikipedia:Citation NeededChristina RomerExecutive Order 6102A Monetary History Of The United StatesAnna J. SchwartzFederal Reserve SystemChairman Of The Federal ReserveSunday RoastEnlargeFort Worth, TexasMobilizationNational DebtWikipedia:Citation NeededWikipedia:VerifiabilityHelp:Introduction To Referencing With Wiki Markup/1Help:Maintenance Template RemovalEnlargeNazi GermanyHistory Of Newfoundland And LabradorGreat Depression In AustraliaCivil UnrestGreat Depression In CanadaEnlargeTorontoOntarioDust BowlMeasures Of National Income And OutputGreat Depression In ChileLeague Of NationsChileAusterity1939 Chillán EarthquakePopular Front (Chile)Pedro Aguirre CerdaCORFOImport Substitution IndustrializationProtectionismNanjing DecadeSilver StandardNationalist GovernmentGreat Depression In FranceFebruary 6, 1934 RiotsPopular Front (France)Section Française De L'Internationale OuvrièreLéon BlumWorld War IIWeimar RepublicEnlargeAdolf HitlerWall Street CrashDawes PlanYoung PlanCredit AnstaltHyperinflationWeimar RepublicGerman Election, July 1932AutarkyEconomic History Of Greece And The Greek WorldBank Of GreeceIoannis MetaxasSpanish Civil WarEconomic History Of The Republic Of IrelandMary E. DalyEconomic History Of ItalyEconomy Of Italy Under FascismIndustrial Reconstruction InstituteTakahashi KorekiyoKeynesian EconomicsDeficit SpendingYenFebruary 26 IncidentChilling Effect (term)ToyotaLight IndustryGreat Depression In Latin AmericaChileBoliviaPeruLatin AmericaGreat Depression In The NetherlandsThe NetherlandsNationaal Socialistische BewegingHistory Of New ZealandNew ZealandAucklandDunedinWellingtonEconomic History Of PortugalDitadura NacionalAntónio De Oliveira SalazarPrime Minister Of PortugalEstado Novo (Portugal)AuthoritarianCorporatistBudget BalanceAutarkyCarlos E. ChardónLuis Muñoz MarínPuerto Rico Reconstruction AdministrationGreat Depression In South AfricaCarnegie Commission Of Investigation On The Poor White Question In South AfricaAfrikanerNational Party (South Africa)South African PartyCommunist StateWalter DurantySoviet Famine Of 1932–1933Economic History Of SpainSpanish Civil WarEconomy Of SwedenIvar KreugerSwedish Social Democratic PartyPer Albin HanssonInterventionism (economics)Welfare StatePrime Minister Of SwedenAxel Pehrsson-BramstorpRattanakosin KingdomPrajadhipokSiamese Revolution Of 1932Great Depression In The United KingdomInterwar BritainEnlargeWorld War IGold StandardNational Government (United Kingdom)GlasgowNational Hunger March, 1932Hunger MarchesEnglish MidlandsSouthern EnglandMiddle ClassGreat Depression In The United StatesNew DealEnlargeSmoot–Hawley Tariff ActNational Credit CorporationEnlargeBonus ArmyShanty TownHoovervilleFederal Home Loan Bank ActEmergency Relief And Construction ActPublic WorksReconstruction Finance CorporationBank RunRealigning ElectionFranklin Delano RooseveltEnlargeSouth DakotaDust BowlFranklin Delano RooseveltDust BowlDisplaced PersonsDemandEmergency Banking ActUnited States Department Of TreasurySecurities Act Of 1933Securities Exchange Act Of 1934Securities And Exchange CommissionDeposit AccountFederal Deposit Insurance CorporationGlass–Steagall ActAgricultural Adjustment ActNational Recovery AdministrationDeflationMinimum WagePurchasing PowerWorking ClassSchechter V. United StatesSupreme Court Of The United StatesEnlargeCivilian Conservation CorpsFirst New DealAlphabet AgenciesReconstruction Finance CorporationSecond New DealSocial Security (United States)Fair DealWorks Progress AdministrationNational Labor Relations BoardGross Domestic ProductEconomic IndicatorDurable GoodEnlargeWorks Progress AdministrationConservative CoalitionSocialismSocial DemocracyPlanned EconomyMarshall PlanKeynesianismMilton FriedmanNeoliberalNeoliberalismChicago School Of EconomicsRonald ReaganMargaret ThatcherUnited KingdomJohn SteinbeckThe Grapes Of WrathThe Grapes Of WrathJohn SteinbeckNobel PrizePulitzer PrizeAgricultureOf Mice And MenTo Kill A MockingbirdThe Blind AssassinFederal Writers' ProjectKit KittredgeAmerican GirlValerie TrippWalter RaneCincinnatiKit Kittredge: An American GirlDear AmericaIndianapolisDepression (economics)Lionel RobbinsEnlargePanic Of 1873Long DepressionDepression (economics)Panic Of 1819James MonroeDepression Of 1920–21Calvin CoolidgePanic Of 1907Panic Of 1910–11Long DepressionWikipedia:Citation NeededDissolution Of The Soviet UnionStandard Of LivingPost-Soviet StatesEastern Bloc1998 Russian Financial CrisisEconomy Of MoldovaSoviet Central AsiaCaucasusWikipedia:Citation NeededWikipedia:VerifiabilityHelp:Introduction To Referencing With Wiki Markup/1Help:Maintenance Template RemovalComparisons Between The Great Recession And The Great DepressionLate-2000s RecessionGreat RecessionCauses Of The Great RecessionFederal ReserveBen BernankeLate-2000s RecessionDow Jones Industrial AverageFinancial Crisis Of 2007–2008Book:Great DepressionPortal:1930sCauses Of The Great DepressionCities In The Great DepressionDust BowlEntertainment During The Great DepressionGreat ContractionList Of Depression-era OutlawsTimeline Of The Great DepressionAftermath Of World War IEconomic CollapseInvoluntary UnemploymentList Of Economic CrisesInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-07-319397-6Willard CochraneLeague Of NationsUniversity Of Wisconsin–MadisonNational Climatic Data CenterDigital Object IdentifierInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-0787657017Category:CS1 Maint: Extra Text: Authors ListLawrence KleinInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-8078-2315-5International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9781843765509Ben BernankePrinceton University PressInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-691-01698-4WorldNetDailyThe New York Review Of BooksAmerican Media (publisher)International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-0-912986-39-5International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-1-84376-335-2Digital Object IdentifierDigital Object IdentifierJSTORInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9781843765509JSTORDigital Object IdentifierInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9780262261197John Cunningham WoodInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9780415310574Foundation For Economic EducationLudwig Von Mises InstituteBusiness InsiderInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-1-905192-53-3International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9780198042013International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-1-84376-335-2Angus MaddisonWikipedia:Link RotBarry EichengreenInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-19-506431-3Barry EichengreenInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-19-506431-3Mount Holyoke CollegeRobert WhaplesThe Journal Of Economic HistoryCambridge University PressDigital Object IdentifierJSTORJSTORPaul KrugmanNew York TimesFederal Reserve Bank Of New YorkInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-0-691-01698-6International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9781317876076International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9780230802148International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9781442610033John Kenneth GalbraithDaniel YerginPublic Broadcasting ServiceChristina RomerDigital Object IdentifierDigital Object IdentifierInternational Standard Serial NumberWayback MachineWayback MachineAdam ToozeChalmers JohnsonMuseum Of New Zealand Te Papa TongarewaInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9789609979368The Harvest Of SorrowInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-19-532487-0Göran TherbornWayback MachineInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/1-85728-533-6International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-416-36010-6International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-0-340-965887Wayback MachineWayback MachineDigital Object IdentifierWayback MachineWayback MachineInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-618-34086-6International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/0-618-34087-4Lanny EbensteinThe Grapes Of WrathJohn SteinbeckInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9781434977090International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9780190660727International Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9781420632187History News NetworkDigital Object IdentifierJSTORWikipedia:Link RotThe New York TimesTime (magazine)Paul KrugmanThe New York TimesThe Wall Street JournalMSN MoneyThe Daily TelegraphDigital Object IdentifierJSTORJohn Kenneth GalbraithAndrey KorotayevInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/978-3-319-17780-9Donald MarkwellMaynard KeynesInternational Standard Book NumberSpecial:BookSources/9789609979368Great Depression In The United StatesJoseph SchumpeterThe Huffington PostUniversity Of VirginiaLawrence ReedHistory (U.S. TV Channel)George Washington UniversityTemplate:Great DepressionTemplate Talk:Great DepressionCauses Of The Great DepressionWall Street Crash Of 1929Smoot–Hawley Tariff ActDust BowlNew DealRecession Of 1937–1938Great Depression In AustraliaGreat Depression In CanadaGreat Depression In ChileGreat Depression In Central EuropeGreat Depression In FranceWeimar RepublicGreat Depression In IndiaGreat DepressionGreat Depression In Latin AmericaGreat Depression In The NetherlandsGreat Depression In South AfricaGreat Depression In The United KingdomGreat Depression In The United StatesCities In The Great DepressionCategory:Great DepressionTemplate:New DealTemplate Talk:New DealNew DealNew Deal CoalitionBrain TrustAmerican Liberty LeagueList Of Critics Of The New DealEmergency Banking ActEconomy ActAgricultural Adjustment ActCivilian Conservation CorpsCivil Works AdministrationCommunications Act Of 1934Executive Order 6102Homeowners Refinancing ActFarm Credit AdministrationFederal Deposit Insurance CorporationFederal Emergency Relief AdministrationFrazier–Lemke Farm Bankruptcy ActGlass–Steagall LegislationNational Industrial Recovery ActNational Housing Act Of 1934National Recovery AdministrationNational Youth AdministrationPublic Works AdministrationPublic Works Of Art ProjectReciprocal Tariff ActRailroad Retirement ActSecurities Act Of 1933Tennessee Valley AuthorityWorks Progress AdministrationFederal Project Number OneFederal Energy Regulatory CommissionFarm Security AdministrationJudicial Procedures Reform ActGuffey Coal ActNational Labor Relations BoardNational Labor Relations ActRural Electrification ActRural Utilities ServiceSocial Security (United States)United States Housing AuthorityFranklin D. RooseveltHarold L. IckesFrances PerkinsHarry HopkinsHenry Morgenthau, Jr.Huey LongHerbert HooverRobert F. WagnerCategory:New DealTemplate:US RecessionsTemplate Talk:US RecessionsList Of Recessions In The United StatesPanic Of 1796–97Panic Of 1819Panic Of 1837Panic Of 1857Long DepressionDepression Of 1882–85Panic Of 1893Panic Of 1907Post–World War I RecessionDepression Of 1920–21Great Depression In The United StatesRecession Of 1937–38Recession Of 1949Recession Of 1953Recession Of 1958Recession Of 1960–61Recession Of 1969–701973–75 RecessionEarly 1980s Recession In The United StatesEarly 1990s Recession In The United StatesEarly 2000s RecessionGreat Recession In The United StatesTemplate:United States TopicsTemplate Talk:United States TopicsUnited StatesHistory Of The United StatesTimeline Of United States HistoryPre-Columbian EraColonial History Of The United StatesThirteen ColoniesColonial American Military HistoryContinental CongressAmerican RevolutionAmerican Revolutionary WarAmerican FrontierAmerica's Critical PeriodTimeline Of Drafting And Ratification Of The United States ConstitutionFederalist EraWar Of 1812United States Territorial AcquisitionsTerritorial Evolution Of The United StatesMexican–American WarAmerican Civil WarReconstruction EraAmerican Indian WarsGilded AgeProgressive EraAfrican-American Civil Rights Movement (1865–1896)African-American Civil Rights Movement (1896–1954)African-American Civil Rights Movement (1954–1968)Spanish–American WarAmerican ImperialismHistory Of The United States (1865–1918)Roaring TwentiesMilitary History Of The United States During World War IIUnited States Home Front During World War IIGerman American BundAmerican CenturyCold WarKorean WarSpace RaceSecond-wave FeminismVietnam WarHistory Of The United States (1991–2008)War On TerrorWar In Afghanistan (2001–present)Iraq WarHistory Of The United States (2008–present)Outline Of The United StatesDemographic History Of The United StatesTimeline Of United States DiscoveriesEconomic History Of The United StatesHistory Of United States Debt CeilingTimeline Of United States InventionsTimeline Of United States Inventions (before 1890)Timeline Of United States Inventions (1890–1945)Timeline Of United States Inventions (1946–91)Timeline Of United States Inventions (after 1991)Military History Of The United StatesPostage Stamps And Postal History Of The United StatesTechnological And Industrial History Of The United StatesGeography Of The United StatesUnited States TerritoryCounty (United States)Washington, D.C.Federal EnclaveIndian ReservationTerritories Of The United StatesUnited States Minor Outlying IslandsLists Of Populated Places In The United StatesU.S. StateList Of Earthquakes In The United StatesList Of Extreme Points Of The United StatesList Of Islands Of The United StatesList Of Mountains Of The United StatesList Of Mountain Peaks Of The United StatesList Of Mountain RangesAppalachian MountainsRocky MountainsNational Park ServiceList Of Areas In The United States National Park SystemList Of Regions Of The United StatesEast Coast Of The United StatesWest Coast Of The United StatesGreat PlainsGulf Coast Of The United StatesMid-Atlantic (United States)Midwestern United StatesNew EnglandPacific StatesCentral United StatesEastern United StatesNorthern United StatesNortheastern United StatesNorthwestern United StatesSouthern United StatesSoutheastern United StatesSouthwestern United StatesWestern United StatesList Of Rivers Of The United StatesColorado RiverColumbia RiverMississippi RiverMissouri RiverOhio RiverRio GrandeYukon RiverTime In The United StatesDrinking Water Supply And Sanitation In The United StatesPolitics Of The United StatesFederal Government Of The United StatesCabinet Of The United StatesUnited States Federal Civil ServiceUnited States Federal Executive DepartmentsExecutive Office Of The President Of The United StatesIndependent Agencies Of The United States GovernmentFederal Law Enforcement In The United StatesPresident Of The United StatesPublic Policy Of The United StatesUnited States CongressUnited States House Of RepresentativesCurrent Members Of The United States House Of RepresentativesSpeaker Of The United States House Of RepresentativesUnited States SenateCurrent Members Of The United States SenatePresident Pro Tempore Of The United States SenateVice President Of The United StatesFederal Judiciary Of The United StatesUnited States Courts Of AppealsUnited States District CourtSupreme Court Of The United StatesLaw Of The United StatesUnited States Bill Of RightsCivil Liberties In The United StatesCode Of Federal RegulationsUnited States ConstitutionFederalism In The United StatesFederal PreemptionSeparation Of Powers Under The United States ConstitutionFederal ReporterUnited States CodeUnited States ReportsUnited States Intelligence CommunityCentral Intelligence AgencyDefense Intelligence AgencyFederal Bureau Of InvestigationNational Geospatial-Intelligence AgencyNational Reconnaissance OfficeNational Security AgencyDirector Of National IntelligenceUniformed Services Of The United StatesUnited States Armed ForcesUnited States ArmyUnited States Marine CorpsUnited States NavyUnited States Air ForceUnited States Coast GuardNational Guard Of The United StatesNOAA Commissioned Officer CorpsUnited States Public Health Service Commissioned Corps51st StatePolitical Status Of Puerto RicoDistrict Of Columbia Statehood MovementElections In The United StatesElectoral College (United States)Foreign Relations Of The United StatesForeign Policy Of The United StatesHawaiian Sovereignty MovementPolitical Ideologies In The United StatesAnti-AmericanismAmerican ExceptionalismAmerican NationalismLocal Government In The United StatesPolitical Parties In The United StatesDemocratic Party (United States)Republican Party (United States)Third Party (United States)Red States And Blue StatesPurple AmericaList Of Federal Political Scandals In The United StatesState Governments Of The United StatesGovernor (United States)State Legislature (United States)State Court (United States)Uncle SamEconomy Of The United StatesEconomy Of The United States By SectorAgriculture In The United StatesBanking In The United StatesCommunications In The United StatesEnergy In The United StatesInsurance In The United StatesManufacturing In The United StatesMining In The United StatesTourism In The United StatesForeign Trade Of The United StatesTransportation In The United StatesList Of Companies Of The United StatesList Of Companies Of The United States By StateUnited States DollarList Of Exports Of The United StatesUnited States Federal BudgetFederal Reserve SystemFinancial Position Of The United StatesLabor Unions In The United StatesNational Debt Of The United StatesSocial Programs In The United StatesTaxation In The United StatesUnemployment In The United StatesWall StreetSociety Of The United StatesCulture Of The United StatesAmericanaArchitecture Of The United StatesCinema Of The United StatesCuisine Of The United StatesDance In The United StatesDemography Of The United StatesEducation In The United StatesFamily Structure In The United StatesFashion In The United StatesFlag Of The United StatesFolklore Of The United StatesLanguages Of The United StatesAmerican EnglishIndigenous Languages Of The AmericasAmerican Sign LanguageBlack American Sign LanguageHawai'i Sign LanguagePlains Indian Sign LanguageArabic Language In The United StatesChinese Language And Varieties In The United StatesFrench Language In The United StatesGerman Language In The United StatesItalian Language In The United StatesRussian Language In The United StatesSpanish Language In The United StatesAmerican LiteratureMedia Of The United StatesHistory Of American JournalismInternet In The United StatesHistory Of American NewspapersRadio In The United StatesTelevision In The United StatesMusic Of The United StatesNaming In The United StatesAmericansAmerican PhilosophyPublic Holidays In The United StatesReligion In The United StatesSexuality In The United StatesSports In The United StatesTheater In The United StatesVisual Art Of The United StatesSocial Class In The United StatesAffluence In The United StatesAmerican DreamEducational Attainment In The United StatesHomelessness In The United StatesHome-ownership In The United StatesHousehold Income In The United StatesIncome Inequality In The United StatesAmerican Middle ClassPersonal Income In The United StatesPoverty In The United StatesProfessional And Working Class Conflict In The United StatesStandard Of Living In The United StatesWealth In The United StatesSocial Issues In The United StatesAges Of Consent In The United StatesCapital Punishment In The United StatesCrime In The United StatesIncarceration In The United StatesCriticism Of The United States GovernmentDiscrimination In The United StatesAffirmative Action In The United StatesAntisemitism In The United StatesIntersex Rights In The United StatesIslamophobia In The United StatesLGBT Rights In The United StatesRacism In The United StatesSame-sex Marriage In The United StatesFederal Drug Policy Of The United StatesEnergy Policy Of The United StatesEnvironmental Movement In The United StatesGun Politics In The United StatesHealth Care In The United StatesAbortion In The United StatesHealth Insurance In The United StatesHunger In The United StatesObesity In The United StatesTobacco In The United StatesHuman Rights In The United StatesImmigration To The United StatesIllegal Immigration To The United StatesInternational Rankings Of The United StatesNational Security Of The United StatesMass Surveillance In The United StatesTerrorism In The United StatesSeparation Of Church And State In The United StatesOutline Of The United StatesIndex Of United States-related ArticlesBook:United StatesCategory:United StatesPortal:United StatesTemplate:EconomicsTemplate Talk:EconomicsEconomicsEconomic TheoryEconometricsApplied EconomicsMacroeconomicsAdaptive ExpectationsAggregate DemandBalance Of PaymentsBusiness CycleCapacity UtilizationCapital FlightCentral BankConsumer ConfidenceCurrencyDemand ShockDepression (economics)Dynamic Stochastic General EquilibriumEconomic GrowthEconomic IndicatorEconomic RentEffective DemandThe General Theory Of Employment, Interest And MoneyHyperinflationInflationInterestInterest RateInvestment (macroeconomics)IS–LM ModelMicrofoundationsMonetary PolicyMoneyNAIRUNational AccountsPurchasing Power ParityRate Of ProfitRational ExpectationsRecessionSavingShrinkflationStagflationSupply ShockUnemploymentList Of Important Publications In EconomicsMicroeconomicsAggregation ProblemBudget SetConsumer ChoiceConvexity In EconomicsCost–benefit AnalysisDeadweight LossDistribution (economics)DuopolyEconomic EquilibriumShortageEconomic SurplusEconomies Of ScaleEconomies Of ScopeElasticity (economics)Expected Utility HypothesisExternalityGeneral Equilibrium TheoryIndifference CurveIntertemporal ChoiceMarginal CostMarket FailureMarket StructureMonopolyMonopsonyNon-convexity (economics)OligopolyOpportunity CostPreference (economics)Production SetProfit (economics)Public GoodReturns To ScaleRisk AversionScarcitySocial Choice TheorySunk CostsSupply And DemandTheory Of The FirmTradeTransaction CostValue (economics)UncertaintyUtilityList Of Important Publications In EconomicsJEL Classification CodesAgricultural EconomicsBusiness EconomicsDemographic EconomicsDevelopment EconomicsEconomic HistoryEducation EconomicsEngineering EconomicsEnvironmental EconomicsFinancial EconomicsHealth EconomicsIndustrial OrganizationInternational EconomicsKnowledge EconomyLabour EconomicsLaw And EconomicsMonetary EconomicsNatural Resource EconomicsPublic EconomicsService EconomyTransport EconomicsUrban EconomicsWelfare EconomicsEconomic MethodologyBehavioral EconomicsComputational EconomicsEconometricsEconomic SystemExperimental EconomicsMathematical EconomicsList Of Important Publications In EconomicsHistory Of Economic ThoughtAncient Economic ThoughtAustrian School Of EconomicsChicago School Of EconomicsClassical EconomicsFeminist EconomicsHeterodox EconomicsInstitutional EconomicsKeynesian EconomicsMainstream EconomicsMarxian EconomicsNeoclassical EconomicsPost-Keynesian EconomicsSchools Of Economic ThoughtEconomistKenneth ArrowGary BeckerFrancis Ysidro EdgeworthMilton FriedmanRagnar FrischFriedrich HayekHarold HotellingJohn Maynard KeynesTjalling KoopmansPaul KrugmanRobert Lucas Jr.Jacob MarschakAlfred MarshallKarl MarxJohn Von NeumannVilfredo ParetoDavid RicardoPaul SamuelsonJoseph SchumpeterAmartya SenHerbert A. SimonAdam SmithRobert SolowLéon WalrasCategory:EconomistsInternational OrganizationAsia-Pacific Economic CooperationEconomic Cooperation OrganizationEuropean Free Trade AssociationInternational Monetary FundOrganisation For Economic Co-operation And DevelopmentWorld BankWorld Trade OrganizationCategory:EconomicsIndex Of Economics ArticlesCategory:Economics ListsOutline Of EconomicsList Of Important Publications In EconomicsPortal:Business And EconomicsTemplate:EmploymentTemplate Talk:EmploymentEmploymentCasual Employment (contract)Contingent WorkFull-timePart-time ContractSelf-employmentSkilled WorkerIndependent ContractorTemporary WorkTenureLaborerWage LabourRecruitmentApplication For EmploymentBackground CheckBusiness NetworkingEmployment ContractCover LetterCurriculum VitaeDrug TestE-recruitmentEmployment CounsellorExecutive SearchInduction ProgrammeJob FairJob FraudJob HuntingJob InterviewLabour BrokeringOverqualificationOnboardingPersonality-job Fit TheoryPerson-environment FitProbation (workplace)Recommendation LetterRésuméSimultaneous Recruiting Of New GraduatesUnderemploymentWork-at-home SchemeCooperativeEmployeeEmployerInternshipJob (role)Permanent EmploymentPermatempSupervisorVolunteeringSocial ClassBlue-collar WorkerGold-collar WorkerGreen-collar WorkerGrey-collarPink-collar WorkerWhite-collar WorkerCareerTrainingApprenticeshipAvocationCareer AssessmentCareer CounselingCareer DevelopmentCoachingCreative ClassEducationContinuing EducationContinuing Professional DevelopmentE-learningEmployabilityFurther EducationGraduate SchoolInduction TrainingInitial Professional DevelopmentKnowledge WorkerLicensureLifelong LearningPractice-based Professional LearningProfessional AssociationProfessional CertificationProfessional DevelopmentProfessional SchoolReflective PracticeRetrainingVocational EducationVocational SchoolVocational UniversityMentorshipOccupational Outlook HandbookPractice FirmProfessionTradesmanVocationBreak (work)Career BreakFurloughGap YearLeave Of AbsenceLong Service LeaveNo Call, No ShowSabbaticalSick LeaveTime ClockSchedule (workplace)Four-day WeekEight-hour DayFlextimeOvertimeRetroactive OvertimeShift WorkTelecommutingWorking TimeWorkweek And WeekendWageIncome BracketIncome TaxLiving WageMaximum WageNational Average SalaryList Of Countries By Average WageList Of Countries In Europe By Monthly Average WageMinimum WageList Of Minimum Wages In CanadaMinimum Wage OrdinanceList Of Sovereign States In Europe By Minimum WageList Of U.S. Minimum WagesProgressive WageProgressive WageOvertime RatePaid Time OffPerformance-related PaySalarySalary CapWorking PoorEmployee BenefitsAnnual LeaveCasual FridayDay CareDisability InsuranceHealth InsuranceLife InsuranceParental LeavePensionSick LeaveTake-home VehicleOccupational Safety And HealthEpilepsy And EmploymentHuman Factors And ErgonomicsIndustrial NoiseKarōshiProtective ClothingOccupational BurnoutOccupational DiseaseOccupational Exposure LimitOccupational Health PsychologyOccupational InjuryOccupational StressRepetitive Strain InjurySick Building SyndromeWork AccidentOccupational FatalityWorkers' CompensationWorkplace PhobiaWorkplace WellnessEqual OpportunityAffirmative ActionEqual Pay For WomenGender Pay GapGlass CeilingCorporate AbuseAccounting ScandalsCorporate BehaviourCorporate CrimeControl FraudList Of Corporate ScandalsEmployment DiscriminationDress CodeEmployee HandbookEmployee MonitoringEvaluation (workplace)Labour LawSexual HarassmentSleeping While On DutyWage TheftWhistleblowerWorkplace BullyingWorkplace HarassmentWorkplace IncivilityBoreoutCivil ConscriptionConscriptionDead-end JobExtreme CareerismJob SatisfactionOrganizational CommitmentMcJobRefusal Of WorkSlaveryDebt BondageHuman TraffickingLabor CampPenal LabourPeonTruck SystemUnfree LabourWage SlaveryWorkaholicWork AversionWork EthicWork–life BalanceDownshiftingSlow LivingTermination Of EmploymentAt-will EmploymentDismissal (employment)Banishment RoomConstructive DismissalWrongful DismissalEmployee Exit ManagementExit InterviewLayoffNotice PeriodPink Slip (employment)ResignationLetter Of ResignationRestructuringRetirementMandatory RetirementRetirement AgeSeverance PackageGolden HandshakeGolden ParachuteTurnover (employment)UnemploymentBarriers To EntryDepression (economics)Long DepressionDiscouraged WorkerFrictional UnemploymentFull EmploymentGraduate UnemploymentInvoluntary UnemploymentJobless RecoveryPhillips CurveRecessionGreat RecessionJob Losses Caused By The Great RecessionList Of RecessionsRecession-proof JobReserve Army Of LabourTypes Of UnemploymentUnemployment ConventionUnemployment BenefitsUnemployment ExtensionUnemployment InsuranceList Of Countries By Unemployment RateList Of Countries By Employment RateEmployment-to-population RatioStructural UnemploymentTechnological UnemploymentWage CurveYouth UnemploymentTemplate:Aspects Of CorporationsTemplate:Aspects Of JobsTemplate:Aspects Of OccupationsTemplate:Aspects Of OrganizationsTemplate:Aspects Of WorkplacesTemplate:Corporate TitlesTemplate:Organized Labor NavboxHelp:Authority ControlLibrary Of Congress Control NumberIntegrated Authority FileHelp:CategoryCategory:Great DepressionCategory:1920s Economic HistoryCategory:1930s Economic HistoryCategory:Financial CrisesCategory:World EconomyCategory:CS1 Maint: Extra Text: Authors ListCategory:All Articles With Dead External LinksCategory:Articles With Dead External Links From May 2017Category:Articles With Permanently Dead External LinksCategory:Pages With Login Required References Or SourcesCategory:Webarchive Template Wayback LinksCategory:Articles With Dead External Links From January 2016Category:Wikipedia Pages Semi-protected Against VandalismCategory:All Articles With Unsourced StatementsCategory:Articles With Unsourced Statements From June 2016Category:Articles With Unsourced Statements From May 2016Category:Articles Needing Additional References From May 2016Category:All Articles Needing Additional ReferencesCategory:Articles To Be Split From September 2017Category:All Articles To Be SplitCategory:Articles With Unsourced Statements From February 2012Category:Articles Containing Potentially Dated Statements From 2009Category:All Articles Containing Potentially Dated StatementsCategory:Articles With Unsourced Statements From October 2015Category:Wikipedia Articles With LCCN IdentifiersCategory:Wikipedia Articles With GND IdentifiersDiscussion About Edits From This IP Address [n]A List Of Edits Made From This IP Address [y]View The Content Page [c]Discussion About The Content Page [t]This Page Is Protected. You Can View Its Source [e]Visit The Main Page [z]Guides To Browsing WikipediaFeatured Content – The Best Of WikipediaFind Background Information On Current EventsLoad A Random Article [x]Guidance On How To Use And Edit WikipediaFind Out About WikipediaAbout The Project, What You Can Do, Where To Find ThingsA List Of Recent Changes In The Wiki [r]List Of All English Wikipedia Pages Containing Links To This Page [j]Recent Changes In Pages Linked From This Page [k]Upload Files [u]A List Of All Special Pages [q]Wikipedia:AboutWikipedia:General Disclaimer



view link view link view link view link view link